Skip to main content

Full text of "BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE - WENDELL BERRY"

See other formats


ringing 

it to the Table 



BRINGING IT 
TO THE TABLE 

ON FARMING AND FOOD 

WENDELL BERRY 

INTRODUCTION BY MICHAEL POLLAN 

BANYAN TREE 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 

on Farming and Food 

WENDELL BERRY 

First Published in India 2013 

BANYAN TREE 
1-B Dhenu Market, 2nd Floor 
Indore - 452003 (India) 
Phone: 91-731-2531488, 2532243 
Mobile: 91-9425904428 
Email : banyantreebookstore@gmail.com 
Website: www.banyantreebookstore.weebly.com 
Avww.banyantreebookstore.com 

Copyright © 2009 by Wendell Berry 

"Published by arrangements with Counterpoint LLC" 

All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, Stored in 
retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electrical, 
mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior per- 
mission of the publisher. 

ISBN: 

Layout & Cover: Shubham Patil 



Printed and Bound in India 



For Sale in Indian Subcontinent only 



CONTENTS 



Introduction / 7 

Part I s Farming 

Nature as Measure / 17 
Stupidity in Concentration / 25 
Agricultural Solutions for Agricultural Problems / 33 
A Defense of the Family Farm / 43 
Let the Farm Judge / 59 
Energy in Agriculture / 65 
Conservationist and Agrarian / 73 
Sanitation and the Small Farm / 85 
Renewing Husbandry / 91 

Part II: Farmers 

Seven Amish Farms / 107 
A Good Farmer of the Old School / 119 
Charlie Fisher / 129 
A Talent for Necessity / 137 

Elmer Lapp's Place / 147 
On The Soil and Health / 157 
Agriculture from the Roots Up / 169 

Part III: Food 

Author's Note / 179 
From That Distant Land / 181 
From Hannah Coulter / 189 
From Andy Catlett / 193 
From "Miser/' / 201 
From The Memory of Old Jack / 203 
From Jayber Crow / 209 
From Hannah Coulter / 213 
The Pleasures of Eating / 215 



Introduction 

by Michael Pollan 



A FEW WEEKS AFTER Michelle Obama planted an organic vegetable gar- 
den on the South Lawn of the White House in March 2009, the busi- 
ness section of the Sunday NewYork Times published a cover story bearing 
the headline "Is a Food Revolution Now in Season?" The article, written by 
the paper's agriculture reporter, said that "after being largely ignored for 
years by Washington, advocates of organic and locally grown food have 
found a receptive ear in the White House." 

Certainly these are heady days for people who have been working to 
reform the way Americans grow food and feed themselves— the "food move- 
ment" as it is now often called. Markets for alternative kinds of food-local 
and organic and pastured— are thriving, farmers' markets are popping up like 
mushrooms, and for the first time in more than a century the number of 
farmers tallied in the Department of Agriculture's census has gone up rather 
than down. The new secretary of agriculture has dedicated his department 
to "sustainability" and holds meetings with the sorts of farmers and activists 
who not many years ago stood outside the marble walls of the USDA hold- 
ing signs of protest and snarling traffic with their tractors. Cheap words, you 
might say, and it is true that, so far at least, there have been more words than 
deeds, but some of those words are astonishing. Like these: Shortly before 
his election, Barack Obama told a reporter for Time that "our entire agricul- 
tural system is built on cheap oil" and went on to connect the dots between 
the sprawling monocultures of industrial agriculture and, on the one side, 
the energy crisis and, on the other, the health care crisis. 



7 



8 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



I have no idea if Barack Obama has ever read Wendell Berry, but 
Berry's thinking had found its way to his lips. 

Americans today are having a national conversation about food and 
agriculture that it would have been impossible to imagine even a few short 
years ago.To many Americans it must sound like a brand-new conversation, 
with its bracing talk about the high price of cheap food, or the links 
between soil and health, or the impossibility of a society eating well and 
being in good health unless it also farms well. But to read the essays in this 
sparkling anthology, many of them dating back to the 1970s and 1980s, is 
to realize just how little of what we are saying and hearing today Wendell 
Berry hasn't already said, bracingly, before. 

And in that "we" I most definitely, and somewhat abashedly, include 
myself. I challenge you to find an idea or insight in my own recent writings 
on food and farming that isn't prefigured (to put it charitably) in Berry's 
essays on agriculture. There might be one or two in there somewhere, but 
I must say that reading and rereading these essays has been a deeply hum- 
bling experience. 

It has also been a powerful reminder that the national conversation 
now unfolding around the subject of food and farming really began back 
in the 1970s, with the work of Berry and a small handful of his contem- 
poraries, including Francis Moore Lappe, Barry Commoner, and Joan 
Gussow. All four of these writers are supreme dot connectors, deeply skep- 
tical of reductive science, and far ahead not only in their grasp of the sci- 
ence of ecology but in their ability to actually think ecologically: to draw 
lines of connection between a hamburger and the price of oil, or between 
the vibrancy of life in the soil and the health of the plants and animals and 
people eating from that soil. 

I would argue that the conversation got under way in earnest in 1971, 
when Berry published an article in The Last Whole Earth Catalogue introduc- 
ing Americans to the work of Sir Albert Howard, the British agronomist 
whose thinking had deeply influenced Berry's own since he first came 
upon it in 1964. Indeed, much of Berry's thinking about agriculture can be 
read as an extended elaboration of Howard's master idea that farming 
should model itself on natural systems such as forests and prairies, and that 



INTRODUCTION 9 



scientists, farmers, and medical researchers need to reconceive "the whole 
problem of health in soil, plant, animal and man as one great subject." No 
single quotation appears more often in Berry's writing than that one, and 
with good reason: It is manifestly true (as even the most reductive scientists 
are coming to recognize) and, as a guide to thinking through so many of 
our problems, it is inexhaustible. 

That same year, 1971, Lappe published Diet for a Small Planet, which 
linked modern meat production (and in particular the feeding of grain to 
cattle) to the problems of world hunger and the environment. Later in the 
decade, Commoner implicated industrial agriculture in the energy crisis, 
showing us just how much oil we were eating when we ate from the indus- 
trial food chain; and Gussow explained to her nutritionist colleagues that 
the problem of dietary health could not be understood without reference 
to the problem of agriculture. Looking back on this remarkably fertile body 
of work, which told us all we needed to know about the true cost of cheap 
food and the value of good farming, is to register two pangs of regret, one 
personal, the other more political: first, that as a young writer coming to 
these subjects a couple of decades later, I was rather less original than I had 
thought; and second, that as a society we failed to heed a warning that 
might have averted or at least mitigated the terrible predicament in which 
we now find ourselves. 

For what would we give today to have back the "environmental crisis" 
that Berry wrote about so prophetically in the 1970s, a time still innocent 
of the problem of climate change? Or to have back the comparatively man- 
ageable public health problems of that period, before obesity and type 2 
diabetes became "epidemic"? (Most experts date the obesity epidemic to the 
early 1980s.) 

But history will show that we failed to take up the invitation to begin 
thinking ecologically. As soon as oil prices subsided and Jimmy Carter was 
rusticated to Plains, Georgia (along with his cardigan, thermostat, and 
solar panels), we went back to business— and agribusiness— as usual, care- 
lessly dropping the thread of the conversation that Berry had helped to 
start. In the mid-1980s, Ronald Reagan removed Carter's solar panels from 
the roof of the White House, and the issues that Berry and the others were 
raising were pushed to the margins of national politics and culture. I 



10 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



worked as an editor at Harper's Magazine during the 1980s, and occasional- 
ly published Berry's speeches and essays. During the Reagan years Berry 
was often regarded, at least in the Manhattan media precincts I inhabited, 
as a "Luddite" and a "crank" and generally as something of a literary and 
philosophical antique. At a time when everyone else was trading in their 
typewriters for personal computers, I published his short essay about his 
refusal to use a typewriter that elicited howls of derision from readers. In 
those days even the word "agriculture" felt hopelessly out-of-date, some- 
thing that a culture consumed with the idea of post- modernism had exact- 
ly no use for. 

In fact when I began writing about agriculture in the late '80s and '90s, 
I quickly figured out that no editor in Manhattan thought the subject time- 
ly or worthy of his or her attention, and that I would be better off avoiding 
the word entirely and talking instead about food, something people then 
still had some use for and cared about, yet oddly never thought to connect 
to the soil or the work of farmers. 

It was during this period that I began reading Berry's work closely— avid- 
ly, in fact, because I found in it practical answers to questions I was strug- 
gling with in my garden. I had begun growing a little of my own food, not 
on a farm but in the backyard of a second home in the exurbs of New York, 
and had found myself completely ill-prepared, especially when it came to 
challenges posed by critters and weeds. An obedient child of Thoreau and 
Emerson (both of whom mistakenly regarded weeds as emblems of wild- 
ness and gardens as declensions from nature), I honored the wild and kept 
from fencing off my vegetables from the encroaching forest. I don't have to 
tell you how well that turned out.Thoreau did plant a bean field at Walden, 
but he couldn't square his love of nature with the need to defend his crop 
from weeds and birds, and eventually he gave up on agriculture. Thoreau 
went on to declare that "if it were proposed to me to dwell in the neighbor- 
hood of the most beautiful garden that ever human art contrived, or else 
of a dismal swamp, I should certainly decide for the swamp." With that 
slightly obnoxious declaration American writing about nature all but 
turned its back on the domestic landscape. It's not at all surprising that we 
got better at conserving wilderness than at farming and gardening. 

It was Wendell Berry who helped me solve my Thoreau problem, pro- 



INTRODUCTION 1 1 



viding a sturdy bridge over the deep American divide between nature and 
culture. Using the farm rather than the wilderness as his text, Berry taught 
me I had a legitimate quarrel with nature— a lover's quarrel— and showed 
me how to conduct it without reaching for the heavy artillery. He relocat- 
ed wildness from the woods "out there" (beyond the fence) to a handful of 
garden soil or the shoot of a germinating pea, a necessary quality that 
could be not just conserved but cultivated. He marked out a path that led 
us back into nature, no longer as spectators but as full- fledged partici- 
pants. I battened on every word of his I could find, and to me his words 
felt anything but antique— indeed, they were fully as alive, and useful, as 
any writing can be. 

Obviously much more is at stake here than a garden fence. My Thoreau 
problem is another name for the problem of American envi- ronmentalism, 
which historically has had much more to say about leav- ing nature alone 
than about how we might use it well. To the extent that we're finally begin- 
ning to hear a new, more neighborly conversa- tion between American envi- 
ronmentalists and American farmers, not to mention between urban eaters 
and rural food producers, Berry deserves much of the credit for getting it 
started with sentences like these: 

Why should conservationists have a positive interest in . . . farming? 
There are lots of reasons, hut the plainest is: Conservationists eat. To be 
interested in food but not in food production is clearly absurd. Urban 
conservationists may feel entitled to be unconcerned about food produc- 
tion because they are not farmers. But they can't be let off so easily, for 
they are farming by proxy. They can eat only if land is farmed on their 
behalf by somebody somewhere in some fashion. If conservationists will 
attempt to resume responsibility for their need to eat, they will be led 
back fairly directly to all their previous concerns for the welfare of na- 
ture. ("Conservationist and Agrarian," 2002) 

That we are all implicated in farming— that, in his now-famous formulation, 
"eating is an agricultural act"— is perhaps Berry's signal contribution to the 
rethinking of food and farming under way today, and in style as well as con- 
tent this stands as a classically Berry-esque idea: at once perfectly obvious 



12 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 

and completely arresting. To read these essays is to feel that way over and 
over again, to be somehow stopped in your tracks by the plainly self-evi- 
dent. Here are a few more such ideas that await you in the pages ahead: 

We have been winning, to our inestimable loss, a competition against 
our own land and our own people. At present, what we have to show 
for this "victory" is a surplus of food. But this is a surplus achieved by 
the ruin of its sources. ( "Nature as Measure," 1989) 

"Sustainable agriculture" . . . refers to a way of farming that can be con- 
tinued indefinitely because it conforms to the terms imposed upon it by 
the nature of places and the nature of people. ("Stupidity in Concentr- 
ation," 2002) 

Here we come to the heart of the matter— the absolute divorce that the 
industrial economy has achieved between itself and all ideals and stan- 
dards outside itself. ("A Defense of the Family Farm," 1986) 

This old sun-based agriculture was fundamentally alien to the indus- 
trial economy; industrial corporations could make relatively little prof- 
it from it. . . . [But] as farmers became more and more dependant on 
fossil fuel energy, a radical change occurred in their minds. Once 
focused on biology, the life and health of living things, their thinking 
now began to focus on technology and economics. Credit, for example, 
became as pressing an issue as the weather. ("Energy in Agriculture, " 
1979) 

Does the concentration of production in the hands of fewer and fewer 
big operators really serve the ends of cleanliness and health? Or does it 
make easier and more lucrative the possibility of collusion between irre- 
sponsible producers and corrupt inspectors? ("Sanitation and the Small 
Farm," 1977) 

There is, then, a politics of food that, like any politics, involves our free- 
dom.We still (sometimes) remember that we cannot be free if our minds 



INTRODUCTION 13 



and voices are controlled by someone else. But we have neglected to un- 
derstand that we cannot he free if our food and its sources are con- 
trolled by someone else. . . . One reason to eat responsibly is to live free. 
("The Pleasures of Eating," 1989) 

The adjective "prophetic" is often attached to Berry's nonfiction, and while 
I can understand why people would use the word— he has done an unerr- 
ing job over the past forty years of showing us precisely where the errors of 
our ways will lead— his prose never screams or squints in rage. It is always as 
patient and logical, as plumb and square and scrupulous, as well-planed 
woodwork. I have learned as much from the construction of his sentences 
as I have from the construction of his ideas. In my study Berry's books sit 
on the short shelf I reach for whenever I get tangled in a sentence; reading 
a few lines at random will often do the trick, break the knot. To enact that 
unmistakable voice in one's head is to administer a tonic strong enough to 
freshen thought and expression both and, at its best, to scrub the crud of 
received opinion from our everyday thoughtless thinking. 

Let me leave you with one very recent example of Berry at his best, 
drawn from an op-ed piece that he published (with his old friend and col- 
laborator Wes Jackson) shortly after the economy crashed in the fall of 
2008. 

For 50 or 60 years, we have let ourselves believe that as long as we 
have money we will have food.This is a mistake. If we continue our 
offenses against the land and the labor by which we are fed, the food 
supply will decline, and we will have a problem far more complex than 
the failure of our paper economy.The government will bring forth no 
food by providing hundreds of billions of dollars to the agribusiness cor- 
porations. 

I like this passage for its idea-the phrase "paper economy" alone is worth a 
million words of commentary on the financial crisis— but even more for the 
very happy news it brings: that this indispensable voice is still out there 
addressing us in our time of need, and remains as bracing as ever. 



PARTI 
FARMING 



Nature as Measure 



(1989) 



I LIVE IN A part of the country that at one time a good farmer could take 
some pleasure in looking at. When I first became aware of it, in the 
1940s, the better land, at least, was generally well farmed. The farms were 
mostly small and were highly diversified, producing cattle, sheep, and hogs, 
tobacco, corn, and the small grains; nearly all the farmers milked a few 
cows for home use and to market milk or cream. Nearly every farm house- 
hold maintained a garden, kept a flock of poultry, and fattened its own 
meat hogs.There was also an extensive "support system" for agriculture: 
Every community had its blacksmith shop, shops that repaired harness and 
machinery, and stores that dealt in farm equipment and supplies. 

Now the country is not well farmed, and driving through it has become 
a depressing experience. Some good small farmers remain, and their farms 
stand out in the landscape like jewels. But they are few and far between, 
and they are getting fewer every year. The buildings and other improve- 
ments of the old farming are everywhere in decay or have vanished alto- 
gether.The produce of the country is increasingly specialized. The small 
dairies are gone. Most of the sheep flocks are gone, and so are most of the 
enterprises of the old household economy. There is less livestock and more 
cash-grain farming. When cash-grain farming comes in, the fences go, the 
livestock goes, erosion increases, and the fields become weedy. 

Like the farmland, the farm communities are declining and eroding. 
The farmers who are still farming do not farm with as much skill as they 
did forty years ago, and there are not nearly so many farmers farming as 



17 



18 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



there were forty years ago. As the old have died, they have not been 
replaced; as the young come of age, they leave farming or leave the com- 
munity. And as the land and the people deteriorate, so necessarily must the 
support system. None of the small rural towns is thriving as it did forty 
years ago .The proprietors of small businesses give up or die and are not 
replaced. As the farm trade declines, farm equipment franchises are 
revoked. The remaining farmers must drive longer and longer distances for 
machines and parts and repairs. 

Looking at the country now, one cannot escape the conclusion that 
there are no longer enough people on the land to farm it well and to take 
proper care of it. A further and more ominous conclusion is that there is 
no longer a considerable number of people knowledgeable enough to look 
at the country and see that it is not properly cared for— though the face of 
the country is now everywhere marked by the agony of our enterprise of 
self-destruction. 

And suddenly in this wasting countryside there is talk of raising pro- 
duction quotas on Burley tobacco by 24 percent, and tobacco growers are 
coming under pressure from the manufacturers to decrease their use of 
chemicals. Everyone I have talked to is doubtful that we have enough peo- 
ple left in farming to meet the increased demand for either quantity or 
quality, and doubtful that we still have the barnroom to house the 
increased acreage. In other words, the demand going up has met the cul- 
ture coming down. No one can be optimistic about the results. 

Tobacco, I know, is not a food, but it comes from the same resources 
of land and people that food comes from, and this emerging dilemma in 
the production of tobacco can only foreshadow a similar dilemma in the 
production of food. At every point in our food economy, present condi- 
tions remaining, we must expect to come to a time when demand (for 
quantity or quality) going up will meet the culture coming down. The fact 
is that we have nearly destroyed American farming, and in the process have 
nearly destroyed our country. 

How has this happened? It has happened because of the application to 
farming of far too simple a standard. For many years, as a nation, we have 
asked our land only to produce, and we have asked our farmers only to pro- 



NATURE AS MEASURE 19 



duce.We have believed that this single economic standard not only guaran- 
teed good performance but also preserved the ultimate truth and Tightness 
of our aims. We have bought unconditionally the economists' line that 
competition and innovation would solve all problems, and that we would 
finally accomplish a technological end-run around biological reality and 
the human condition. 

Competition and innovation have indeed solved, for the time being, 
the problem of production. But the solution has been extravagant, 
thoughtless, and far too expensive. We have been winning, to our ines- 
timable loss, a competition against our own land and our own people. At 
present, what we have to show for this "victory" is a surplus of food. But 
this is a surplus achieved by the ruin of its sources, and it has been used, 
by apologists for our present economy, to disguise the damage by which it 
was produced. Food, clearly, is the most important economic product- 
except when there is a surplus. When there is a surplus, according to our 
present economic assumptions, food is the least important product.The 
surplus becomes famous as evidence to consumers that they have nothing 
to worry about, that there is no problem, that present economic assump- 
tions are correct. 

But our present economic assumptions are failing in agriculture, and 
to those having eyes to see the evidence is everywhere, in the cities as well 
as in the countryside. The singular demand for production has been 
unable to acknowledge the importance of the sources of production in 
nature and in human culture. Of course agriculture must be productive; 
that is a requirement as urgent as it is obvious. But urgent as it is, it is not 
the first requirement; there are two more requirements equally important 
and equally urgent. One is that if agriculture is to remain productive, it 
must preserve the land, and the fertility and ecological health of the land; 
the land, that is, must be used well. A further requirement, therefore, is that 
if the land is to be used well, the people who use it must know it well, must 
be highly motivated to use it well, must know how to use it well, must have 
time to use it well, and must be able to afford to use it well. Nothing that 
has happened in the agricultural revolution of the last fifty years has dis- 
proved or invalidated these requirements, though everything that has hap- 
pened has ignored or defied them. 



20 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



In light of the necessity that the farmland and the farm people should 
thrive while producing, we can see that the single standard of productivity 
has failed. 

Now we must learn to replace that standard by one that is more com- 
prehensive: the standard of nature. The effort to do this is not new. It was 
begun early in this century by Liberty Hyde Bailey of the Cornell 
University College of Agriculture, by F. H. King of the University of 
Wisconsin College of Agriculture and the United States Department of 
Agriculture, by J. Russell Smith, professor of economic geography at 
Columbia University, by the British agricultural scientist Sir Albert 
Howard, and by others; and it has continued into our own time in the 
work of such scientists as John Todd, Wes Jackson, and others. The stan- 
dard of nature is not so simple or so easy a standard as the standard of pro- 
ductivity. The term "nature" is not so definite or stable a concept as the 
weights and measures of productivity. But we know what we mean when we 
say that the first settlers in any American place recognized that place's agri- 
cultural potential "by its nature"-that is, by the depth and quality of its soil, 
the kind and quality of its native vegetation, and so on. And we know what 
we mean when we say that all too often we have proceeded to ignore the 
nature of our places in farming them. By returning to "the nature of the 
place" as standard, we acknowledge the necessary limits of our own inten- 
tions. Farming cannot take place except in nature; therefore, if nature does 
not thrive, farming cannot thrive. But we know too that nature includes us. 
It is not a place into which we reach from some safe standpoint outside 
it. We are in it and are a part of it while we use it. If it does not thrive, we 
cannot thrive.The appropriate measure of farming then is the world's 
health and our health, and this is inescapably one measure. 

But the oneness of this measure is far different from the singularity of 
the standard of productivity that we have been using; it is far more com- 
plex. One of its concerns, one of the inevitable natural measures, is produc- 
tivity; but it is also concerned for the health of all the creatures belonging 
to a given place, from the creatures of the soil and water to the humans and 
other creatures of the land surface to the birds of the air. The use of nature 
as measure proposes an atonement between ourselves and our world, 
between economy and ecology, between the domestic and the wild. Or it 



NATURE AS MEASURE 21 



proposes a conscious and careful recognition of the interdependence 
between ourselves and nature that in fact has always existed and, if we are 
to live, must always exist. 

Industrial agriculture, built according to the single standard of pro- 
ductivity, has dealt with nature, including human nature, in the manner of 
a monologist or an orator. It has not asked for anything, or waited to hear 
any response. It has told nature what it wanted, and in various clever ways 
has taken what it wanted. And since it proposed no limit on its wants, 
exhaustion has been its inevitable and foreseeable result. This, clearly, is a 
dictatorial or totalitarian form of behavior, and it is as totalitarian in its use 
of people as it is in its use of nature. Its connections to the world and to 
humans and the other creatures become more and more abstract, as its 
economy, its authority, and its power become more and more centralized. 

On the other hand, an agriculture using nature, including human 
nature, as its measure would approach the world in the manner of a con- 
versationalist. It would not impose its vision and its demands upon a world 
that it conceives of as a stockpile of raw material, inert and indifferent to 
any use that may be made of it. It would not proceed directly or soon to 
some supposedly ideal state of things. It would proceed directly and soon 
to serious thought about our condition and our predicament. On all farms, 
farmers would undertake to know responsibly where they are and to "con- 
sult the genius of the place." They would ask what nature would be doing 
there if no one were farming there. They would ask what nature would per- 
mit them to do there, and what they could do there with the least harm to 
the place and to their natural and human neighbors. And they would ask 
what nature would help them to do there. And after each asking, knowing 
that nature will respond, they would attend carefully to her response. The 
use of the place would necessarily change, and the response of the place to 
that use would necessarily change the user. The conversation itself would 
thus assume a kind of creaturely life, binding the place and its inhabitants 
together, changing and growing to no end, no final accomplishment, that 
can be conceived or foreseen. 

Farming in this way, though it certainly would proceed by desire, is not 
visionary in the political or Utopian sense. In a conversation, you always 



22 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



expect a reply. And if you honor the other party to the conversation, if you 
honor the otherness of the other party, you understand that you must not 
expect always to receive a reply that you foresee or a reply that you will like. 
A conversation is immitigably two-sided and always to some degree myste- 
rious; it requires faith. 

For a long time now we have understood ourselves as traveling toward 
some sort of industrial paradise, some new Eden conceived and construct- 
ed entirely by human ingenuity. And we have thought ourselves free to use 
and abuse nature in any way that might further this enterprise. Now we 
face overwhelming evidence that we are not smart enough to recover Eden 
by assault, and that nature does not tolerate or excuse our abuses. If, in 
spite of the evidence against us, we are finding it hard to relinquish our old 
ambition, we are also seeing more clearly every day how that ambition has 
reduced and enslaved us. We see how everything— the whole world— is belit- 
tled by the idea that all creation is moving or ought to move toward an end 
that some body, some human body, has thought up. To be free of that end 
and that ambition would be a delightful and precious thing. Once free of 
it, we might again go about our work and our lives with a seriousness and 
pleasure denied to us when we merely submit to a fate already determined 
by gigantic politics, economics, and technology. 

Such freedom is implicit in the adoption of nature as the measure of 
economic life. The reunion of nature and economy proposes a necessary 
democracy, for neither economy nor nature can be abstract in practice. 
When we adopt nature as measure, we require practice that is locally 
knowledgeable. The particular farm, that is, must not be treated as any 
farm. And the particular knowledge of particular places is beyond the com- 
petence of any centralized power or authority. Farming by the measure of 
nature, which is to say the nature of the particular place, means that farm- 
ers must tend farms that they know and love, farms small enough to know 
and love, using tools and methods that they know and love, in the compa- 
ny of neighbors that they know and love. 

In recent years, our society has been required to think again of the is- 
sues of use and abuse of human beings. We understand, for instance, that 
the inability to distinguish between a particular woman and any woman 



NATURE AS MEASURE 23 



is a condition predisposing to abuse. It is time that we learn to apply the 
same understanding to our country. The inability to distinguish between 
a farm and any farm is a condition predisposing to abuse, and abuse has 
been the result. Rape, indeed, has been the result, and we have seen that 
we are not exempt from the damage we have inflicted. Now we must think 
of marriage. 



Stupidity in Concentration 

(2002) 

I. CONFINEMENT, CONCENTRATION, SEPARATION 

MY TASK HERE is to show the great stupidity of industrial animal pro- 
duction. Factory farms, like this essay, have the aim of cramming as 
much as possible into as small a space as possible. To understand these ani- 
mal factories, we need to keep in mind three principles: confinement, con- 
centration, and separation. 

The principle of confinement in so-called animal science is derived 
from the industrial version of efficiency. The designers of animal factories 
appear to have had in mind the example of concentration camps or pris- 
ons, the aim of which is to house and feed the greatest number in the 
smallest space at the least expense of money, labor, and attention. To sub- 
ject innocent creatures to such treatment has long been recognized as 
heartless. Animal factories make an economic virtue of heartlessness 
toward domestic animals, to which humans owe instead a large debt of 
respect and gratitude. 

The defenders of animal factories typically assume, or wish others to 
assume, that these facilities concentrate animals only. But that is not so. 
They also concentrate the excrement of the animals— which, when proper- 
ly dispersed, is a valuable source of fertility, but, when concentrated, is at 
best a waste, at worst a poison. 

Perhaps even more dangerous is the inevitability that large concentra- 
tions of animals will invite concentrations of disease organisms, which in 



25 



26 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



turn require concentrated and continuous use of antibiotics. And here the 
issue enlarges beyond the ecological problem to what some scientists think 
of as an evolutionary problem: The animal factory becomes a breeding 
ground for treatment-resistant pathogens, exactly as large field monocul- 
tures become breeding grounds for pesticide-resistant pests. 

To concentrate food-producing animals in large numbers in one place 
inevitably separates them from the sources of their feed. Pasture and barn- 
yard animals are removed from their old places in the order of a diversified 
farm, where they roamed about in some freedom, foraging to a significant 
extent for their own food, grazing in open pastures, or recycling barnyard 
and household wastes. Confined in the pens of animal factories, they are 
made dependent almost exclusively upon grains which are grown in large 
monocultures, at a now generally recognized ecological cost, and which 
must be transported to the animals sometimes over long distances. Animal 
factories are energy-wasting enterprises flourishing in a time when we need 
to be thinking of energy conservation. 

The industrialization of agriculture, by concentration and separation, 
overthrows the restraints inherent in the diversity and balance of healthy 
ecosystems and good farms.This results in an unprecedented capacity for 
overproduction, which drives down farm income, which separates yet more 
farmers from their farms. For the independent farmers of the traditional 
small family farm, the animal factories substitute hired laborers, who at 
work are confined in the same unpleasant and unhealthy situation as the 
animals. Production at such a cost is temporary. The cost finally is dimin- 
ishment of the human and ecological capacity to produce. 

Animal factories ought to have been the subject of much government 
concern, if government is in fact concerned about the welfare of the land 
and the people. But, instead, the confined animal feeding industry has been 
the beneficiary of government encouragement and government incentives. 
This is the result of a political brain disease that causes people in power to 
think that anything that makes more money or "creates jobs" is good. 

We have animal factories, in other words, because of a governmental 
addiction to short-term economics. Short-term economics is the practice of 
making as much money as you can as fast as you can by any possible means 



STUPIDITY IN CONCENTRATION 27 



while ignoring the long-term effects. Short-term economics is the eco- 
nomics of self-interest and greed. People who operate on the basis of short- 
term economics accumulate large "externalized" costs, which they charge to 
the future— that is, to the world and to everybody's grandchildren. 

People who are concerned about what their grandchildren will have to 
eat, drink, and breathe tend to be interested in long-term economics. Long- 
term economics involves a great deal besides the question of how to make 
a lot of money in a hurry. Long-term economists such as John Ikerd of the 
University of Missouri believe in applying "the Golden Rule across the gen- 
erations—doing for future generations as we would have them do for us." 
Professor Ikerd says: "The three cornerstones of sustainability are ecological 
soundness, economic viability, and social justice." He thinks that animal 
factories are deficient by all three measures. 

These factories raise issues of public health, of soil and water and air 
pollution, of the quality of human work, of the humane treatment of ani- 
mals, of the proper ordering and conduct of agriculture, and of the longevi- 
ty and healthfulness of food production. 

If the people in our state and national governments undertook to eval- 
uate economic enterprises by the standards of long-term economics, they 
would have to employ their minds in actual thinking. For many of them, 
this would be a shattering experience, something altogether new, but it 
would also cause them to learn things and do things that would improve 
the lives of their constituents. 

II. FACTORY FARMS VERSUS FARMS 

Factory farms increase and concentrate the ecological risks of food pro- 
duction. This is a well-documented matter of fact. The rivers and estu- 
aries of North Carolina, to use only one example, testify to how quickly a 
"private" animal factory can become an ecological catastrophe and a public 
liability. 

A farm, on the other hand, disperses the ecological risks involved in 
food production. A good farm not only disperses these risks, but also mini- 
mizes them. On a good farm, ecological responsibility is inherent in prop- 
er methodologies of land management, and in correct balances between 



28 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



animals and acres, production and carrying capacity. A good farm does not 
put at risk the healthfulness of the land, the water, and the air. 

The ecological differences between a factory farm and a farm may be 
paramount in a time of rapidly accelerating destruction of the natural 
world. But there is also an economic difference that, from the standpoint 
of human communities, is critical. 

A factory farm locks the farmer in at the bottom of a corporate hierar- 
chy. In return for the assumption of great economic and other risks, the 
farmer is permitted to participate minimally in the industry's earnings. In 
return, moreover, for the security of a contract with the corporation, the 
farmer gives up the farm's diversity and versatility, reducing it to a special- 
ist operation with one use. 

According to one company's projections, a farmer would buy into the 
broiler business at a cost of $624, 275. That would be for four houses that 
would produce 506,000 birds per year. Under the company's terms, this 
investment would produce a yearly net income of $23,762. That would be 
an annual return on investment of 3.8 percent. 

I don't know what percentage of annual return this company's share- 
holders expect to realize from their investment. I do know that if it is not 
substantially better than the farmer's percentage, they would be well 
advised to sell out and invest elsewhere. 

The factory farm, rather than serving the farm family and the local 
community, is an economic siphon, sucking value out of the local land- 
scape and the local community into distant bank accounts. 

To entice them to buy Kentuckians' work and products so cheaply, our 
state government has given the animal confinement corporations some 
$200 million in state and federal tax "incentives." In gratitude for these 
gifts, these corporations now wish to be relieved of any mandated public 
liability or responsibility for their activities here. 

I don't know that the arrogance and impudence of this have been 
equaled by any other industry. For not only have these people demonstrat- 
ed, by their contempt for laws and regulations here and elsewhere, their 
intention to be bad neighbors; they come repeatedly before our elected rep- 
resentatives to ask for special exemptions. But in that very request they 



STUPIDITY IN CONCENTRATION 29 



acknowledge the great risks and dangers that are involved in their way of 
doing business. Why should the innocent, why should people with a good 
conscience, want to be exempt from liability? 

It is clear that the advocates of factory farming are not advocates of 
farming. They do not speak for farmers. 

What they support is state-sponsored colonialism— government of, by, 
and for the corporations. 

III. SUSTAINABILITY 

The word "sustainable" is well on its way to becoming a label, like the 
word "organic." And so I want to propose a definition of "sustainable 
agriculture." This phrase, I suggest, refers to a way of farming that can be 
continued indefinitely because it conforms to the terms imposed upon it 
by the nature of places and the nature of people. 

Our present agriculture, in general, is not ecologically sustainable now, 
and it is a long way from becoming so. It is too toxic. It is too dependent 
on fossil fuels. It is too wasteful of soil, of soil fertility, and of water. It is 
destructive of the health of the natural systems that surround and support 
our economic life. And it is destructive of genetic diversity, both domestic 
and wild. 

So far, these problems have not received enough attention from the 
news media or politicians, but the day is coming when they will. A great 
many people who know about agriculture are worrying about these prob- 
lems already. It seems likely that the public, increasingly conscious of the 
issues of personal and ecological health, will sooner or later force the 
political leadership to pay attention. And a lot of farmers and grassroots 
farm organizations are now taking seriously the problem of ecological 
sustainability. 

But there is a related issue that is even more neglected, one that has 
been largely obscured, even for people aware of the requirement of ecolog- 
ical sustainability, by the vogue of the so-called free market and the global 
economy. I am talking about the issue of the economic sustainability of 
farms and farmers, farm families and farm communities. 

It ought to be obvious that in order to have sustainable agriculture, you 



30 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



have got to make sustainable the lives and livelihoods of the people who do 
the work. The land cannot thrive if the people who are its users and care- 
takers do not thrive. Ecological sustainability requires a complex local cul- 
ture as the preserver of the necessary knowledge and skill; and this in turn 
requires a settled, stable, prosperous local population of farmers and other 
land users. It ought to be obvious that agriculture cannot be made sustain- 
able by a dwindling population of economically depressed farmers and a 
growing population of migrant workers. 

Why is our farm population dwindling away? Why are the still-surviv- 
ing farms so frequently in desperate economic circumstances? Why is the 
suicide rate among farmers three times that of the country as a whole? 

There is one reason that is paramount: The present agricultural econ- 
omy, as designed by the agribusiness corporations (and the politicians, 
bureaucrats, economists, and experts who do their bidding), uses farmers 
as expendable "resources" in the process of production, the same way it uses 
the topsoil, the groundwater, and the ecological integrity of farm land- 
scapes. 

From the standpoint of sustainability, either of farmland or farm peo- 
ple, the present agricultural economy is a failure. It is, in fact, a catastro- 
phe. And there is no use in thinking that agriculture can become sustain- 
able by better adapting to the terms imposed by this economy. That is hope- 
less, because its terms are the wrong terms. The purpose of this economy is 
rapid, short-term exploitation, not sustainability. 

The story we are in now is exactly the same story we have been in for 
the last hundred years. It is the story of a fundamental conflict between the 
interests of farmers and farming and the interests of the agribusiness cor- 
porations. It is useless to suppose or pretend that this conflict does not 
exist, or to hope that you can somehow serve both sides at once. The inter- 
ests are different, they are in conflict, and you have to get on one side or 
the other. 

As a case in point, let us consider the economics of Kentucky's chick- 
en factories, which some are pleased to look upon as a help to farmers. The 
Courier-Journal on May 28, 2000, told the story of a McLean County farmer 
who raises 1.2 million chickens a year. His borrowed investment of 



STUPIDITY IN CONCENTRATION 3 1 



$750,000 brings him an annual income of $20,000 to $30,000. This 
declares itself immediately as a "deal" tailor-made for desperate farmers. 
Who besides a desperate farmer would see $20,000 or $30,000 as an 
acceptable annual return on an investment of $750,000 plus a year's work? 
In the poultry-processing corporations that sponsor such "farming," how 
many CEOs would see that as an acceptable return? The fact is that agricul- 
ture cannot be made sustainable in this way. The ecological risks are high, 
and the economic structure is forbidding. How many children of farmers 
in such an arrangement will want to farm? 

Some people would like to claim that this sort of "economic develop- 
ment" is "inevitable." But the only things that seem inevitable about it are 
the corporate greed that motivates it and the careerism of the academic 
experts who try to justify it. On May 28, the Courier-Journal quoted an 
agribusiness apologist at the University of Kentucky's experiment station in 
Princeton, Gary Parker, who said in defense of the animal factories: 
"Agriculture is a high-volume, high-cost, high-risk type business. You have 
to borrow a tremendous amount of money. You have to generate a tremen- 
dous amount of income just to barely make a living." 

The first problem with Mr. Parker's justification is that it amounts to a 
perfect condemnation of this kind of agriculture. In an editorial on June 
4, the Courier-Journal quoted Mr. Parker, and then said that such agricul- 
ture, though compromising and risky, "can generate great rewards." The 
Courier-Journal did not say who would get those "great rewards." We may be 
sure, however, that they will not go to the farmers, who, according to Mr. 
Parker's confession, are just barely making a living. 

The second problem with Mr. Parker's statement is that it is not neces- 
sarily true. In contrast to the factory farm that realizes a profit of $20,000 
or $30,000 on the sale of 1,200,000 chickens, I know a farm family who, 
last year, as a part of a diversified small farm enterprise, produced 2,000 
pastured chickens for a net income of $6,000. This farm enterprise 
involved no large investment for housing or equipment, no large debt, no 
contract, and no environmental risk.The chickens were of excellent quali- 
ty. The customers for them were ordinary citizens, about half of whom were 
from the local rural community. The demand far exceeds the supply. Most 



32 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



of the proceeds for these chickens went to the family that did the work of 
producing them. A substantial portion of that money will be spent in the 
local community. Such a possibility has not been noticed by Mr. Parker or 
the Courier-Journal because, I suppose, it is not "tremendous" and it serves 
the interest of farmers, not corporations. 



Agricultural Solutions for 
Agricultural Problems 



(1978) 



IT MAY TURN out that the most powerful and the most destructive change 
of modern times has been a change in language: the rise of the image, 
or metaphor, of the machine. Until the industrial revolution occurred in 
the minds of most of the people in the so-called developed countries, the 
dominant images were organicThey had to do with living things; they were 
biological, pastoral, agricultural, or familial. God was seen as a "shepherd," 
the faithful as "the sheep of His pasture." One's home country was known 
as one's "motherland." Certain people were said to have the strength of a 
lion, the grace of a deer, the speed of a falcon, the cunning of a fox, etc. 
Jesus spoke of himself as a "bridegroom." People who took good care of the 
earth were said to practice "husbandry." The ideal relationships among peo- 
ple were "brotherhood" and "sisterhood." 

Now we do not flinch to hear men and women referred to as "units" as 
if they were as uniform and interchangeable as machine parts. It is com- 
mon, and considered acceptable, to refer to the mind as a computer: one's 
thoughts are "inputs"; other people's responses are "feedback." And the 
body is thought of as a machine; it is said, for instance, to use food as "fuel"; 
and the best workers and athletes are praised by being compared to 
machines. Work is judged almost exclusively now by its "efficiency," which, 
as used, is a mechanical standard, or by its profitability, which is our only 
trusted index of mechanical efficiency. One's country is no longer loved 



33 



34 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



familially and intimately as a "motherland," but rather priced according to 
its "productivity" of "raw materials" and "natural resources"-valued, that is, 
strictly according to its ability to keep the machines running. And recently 
R. Buckminster Fuller asserted that "the universe physically is itself the 
most incredible technology"-the necessary implication being that God is 
not father, shepherd, or bridegroom, but a mechanic, operating by princi- 
ples which, according to Fuller, "can only be expressed mathematically." 

In view of this revolution of language, which is in effect the uprooting 
of the human mind, it is not surprising to realize that farming too has been 
made to serve under the yoke of this extremely reductive metaphor. 
Farming, according to most of the most powerful people now concerned 
with it, is no longer a way of life, no longer husbandry or even agriculture; 
it is an industry known as "agribusiness," which looks upon a farm as a "fac- 
tory," and upon farmers, plants, animals, and the land itself as interchange- 
able parts or "units of production." 

This view of farming has been dominant now for a generation, and so 
it is not too soon to ask: How well does it work? We must answer that it 
works as any industrial machine works: very "efficiently" according to the 
terms of an extremely specialized accounting. That is to say that it apparent- 
ly makes it possible for about 4 percent of the population to "feed" the rest. 
So long as we keep the focus narrowed to the "food factory" itself, we have 
to be impressed: It is elaborately organized; it is technologically sophisticat- 
ed; it is, by its own definition of the term, marvelously "efficient." 

Only when we widen the focus do we see that this "factory" is in fact a 
failure. Within itself it has the order of a machine, but, like other enterpris- 
es of the industrial vision, it is part of a rapidly widening and deepening 
disorder. It will be sufficient here to list some of the serious problems that 
have a demonstrable connection with industrial agriculture: (1) soil ero- 
sion, (2) soil compaction, (3) soil and water pollution, (4) pests and diseases 
resulting from monoculture and ecological deterioration, (5) depopulation 
of rural communities, and (6) decivilization of the cities. 

The most obvious falsehood of "agribusiness" accounting has to do 
with the alleged "efficiency" of "agribusiness" technology. This is, in the first 
place, an efficiency calculated in the productivity of workers, not of acres. 



AGRICULTURE SOLUTIONS FOR AGRICULTURE PROBLEMS 



35 



In the second place the productivity per "man-hour," as given out by 
"agribusiness" apologists, is dangerously— and, one must assume, intention- 
ally—misleading. For the 4 percent of our population that is left on the 
farm does not, by any stretch of imagination, feed the rest. That 4 percent 
is only a small part, and the worst-paid part, of a food production network 
that includes purchasers, wholesalers, retailers, processors, packagers, trans- 
porters, and the manufacturers and salesmen of machines, building mate- 
rials, feeds, pesticides, herbicides, fertilizers, medicines, and fuel. All these 
producers are at once in competition with each other and dependent on 
each other, and all are dependent on the petroleum industry. 

As for the farmers themselves, they have long ago lost control of their 
destiny. They are no longer "independent farmers," subscribing to that 
ancient and perhaps indispensable ideal, but are agents of their creditors 
and of the market. They are "units of production" who, or which, must per- 
form "efficiently"— regardless of what they get out of it either as investors or 
as human beings. 

In the larger accounting, then, industrial agriculture is a failure on its 
way to being a catastrophe. Why is it a failure? There are, I think, two 
inescapable reasons. 

The first is that the industrial vision is perhaps inherently an over-sim- 
plifying vision, which proceeds on the assumption that consequence is 
always singular; industrialists invariably assume that they are solving for 
X— X being production. In order to solve for X, industrial agriculturists have 
to reduce any agricultural problem to a problem in mechanics-as, for exam- 
ple, modern confinement-feeding techniques became possible only when 
animals could be considered as machines. 

What this vision excludes, as a matter of course, are biology on the one 
hand, and human culture on the other. Once vision is enlarged to include 
these considerations, we see readily that— as wisdom has always counseled 
us— consequences are invariably multiple, self-multiplying, long-lasting, and 
unforeseeable in something like geometric proportion to the size or power 
of the cause. Taking our bearings from traditional wisdom and from the 
insights of the ecologists— which, so far as I can see, confirm traditional wis- 
dom-we realize that in a country the size of the United States, and eco- 



36 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



nomically uniform, the smallest possible agricultural "unit of production" 
is very large indeed. It consists of all the farmland, plus all the farmers, plus 
all the farming communities, plus all the knowledge and the technical 
means of agriculture, plus all the available species of domestic plants and 
animals, plus the natural systems and cycles that surround farming and 
support it, plus the knowledge, taste, judgment, kitchen skills, etc. of all the 
people who buy food. A proper solution to an agricultural problem must 
preserve and promote the good health of this "unit." Nothing less will do. 

The second reason for the failure of industrial agriculture is its waste- 
fulness. In natural or biological systems, waste does not occur. And it is 
easy to produce examples of nonindustrial human cultures in which waste 
was or is virtually unknown. All that is sloughed off in the living arc of a 
natural cycle remains within the cycle; it becomes fertility, the power of life 
to continue. In nature death and decay are as necessary-are, one may 
almost say, as lively— as life; and so nothing is wasted.There is really no such 
thing, then, as natural production; in nature, there is only reproduction. 

But waste— so far, at least— has always been intrinsic to industrial pro- 
duction.There have always been unusable "by-products." Because industrial 
cycles are never complete— because there is no return— there are two charac- 
teristic results of industrial enterprise: exhaustion and contamination. The 
energy industry, for instance, is not a cycle, but only a short arc between an 
empty hole and poisoned air. And farming, which is inherently cyclic, capa- 
ble of regenerating and reproducing itself indefinitely, becomes similarly 
destructive and self-exhausting when transformed into an industry. 
Agricultural pollution is a serious and growing problem. And industrial 
agriculture is forced by its very character to treat the soil itself as a "raw 
material," which it proceeds to "use up." It has been estimated, for instance, 
that at the present rate of cropland erosion Iowa's soil will be exhausted by 
the year 2050. I have seen no attempt to calculate the human cost of such 
farming— by attrition, displacement, social disruption, etc.— I assume 
because it is incalculable. 

This failure of industrial agriculture is not more obvious, or more 
noticed, because many of its worst social and economic consequences have 
collected in the cities, and are erroneously called "urban problems." Also, 



AGRICULTURE SOLUTIONS FOR AGRICULTURE PROBLEMS 37 

because the farm population is now so small, most people know nothing of 
farming, and cannot recognize agricultural problems when they see them. 

But if industrial agriculture is a failure, then how does it continue to 
produce such an enormous volume of food? One reason is that most coun- 
tries where industrial agriculture is practiced have soils that were originally 
good, possessing great natural reserves of fertility. (Industrial agriculture is 
much more quickly destructive in places where the fertility reserves of the 
soil are not great— as in the Amazon basin.) Another reason is that, as nat- 
ural fertility has declined, we have so far been able to subsidize food pro- 
duction by large applications of chemical fertilizer. These have effectively 
disguised the loss of natural fertility, but it is important to emphasize that 
they are a disguise. They delay some of the consequences of failure, but can- 
not prevent them. Chemical fertilizers are required in vast amounts, they 
are increasingly expensive, and most of them come from sources that are 
not renewable. Industrial agriculture is now absolutely dependent on them, 
and this dependence is one of its fundamental weaknesses. 

Another weakness of industrial agriculture is its absolute dependence 
on an enormous and intricate— hence fragile— economic and industrial 
organization. Industrial food production can be gravely impaired or 
stopped by any number of causes, none of which need be agricultural: a 
trucker's strike, an oil shortage, a credit shortage, a manufacturing "error" 
such as the PBB catastrophe in Michigan. 

A third weakness is the absolute dependence of most of the popula- 
tion on industrial agriculture— and the lack of any "backup system." We 
have an unprecedentedly large urban population that has no land to grow 
food on, no knowledge of how to grow it, and less and less knowledge of 
what to do with it after it is grown. That this population can continue to 
eat through shortage, strike, embargo, riot, depression, war-or any of the 
other large-scale afflictions that societies have always been heir to and that 
industrial societies are uniquely vulnerable to-is not a certainty or even a 
faith; it is a superstition. 

As an example of the unexamined confusions and contradictions that 
underlie industrial agriculture, consider Agriculture Secretary Bob 
Bergland's recent remarks on the state of agriculture in China: "From the 



38 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



manpower-production point of view, they're terribly inefficient— 700 mil- 
lion people doing the most pedestrian kind of things. But in production 
per acre, they're enormously successful. They get nine times as many calo- 
ries per acre as we do in the United States." 

This comment is remarkable for its failure to acknowledge any pos- 
sible connection between China's large agricultural work force and its high 
per-acre productivity. In many parts of China, according to one recent 
observer, the agriculture is still much closer to what we call gardening than 
to what we call farming. Because their farming is done on comparatively 
small plots, using a lot of hand labor, Chinese farmers have at their dispos- 
al such high-production techniques as intercropping and close rotations, 
which with us are available only to home gardeners. Many Chinese fields 
have maintained the productivity of gardens for thousands of years, and 
this is directly attributable to the great numbers of the farming population. 
Each acre can be intensively used and cared for, maintained for centuries 
at maximum fertility and yield, because there are enough knowledgeable 
people to do the necessary handwork. 

It is naive to assume, as Mr. Bergland implicitly does, that such an agri- 
culture can be improved by "modernization"— that is, by the introduction of 
industrial standards, methods, and technology. How can this agriculture be 
industrialized without destroying its intensive methods, and thus reducing 
its productivity per acre? How can the so-called pedestrian tasks be taken 
over by machines without displacing people, increasing unemployment, 
degrading the quality of land maintenance, increasing slums and other 
urban blights? How, in other words, can this revolution fail to cause in 
China the same disorders that it has already caused in the United States? I 
do not mean to imply that these questions can be answered simply. My 
point is that before we participate in the industrialization of Chinese agri- 
culture we ought to ask and answer these questions. 

Finally, the Secretary's statement is remarkable for its revealing use of 
the word "pedestrian." This is a usage strictly in keeping with the industri- 
al revolution of our language. The farther industrialization has gone with 
us, and the more it has influenced our values and behavior, the more con- 
temptuous and belittling has the adjective "pedestrian" become. If you want 



AGRICULTURE SOLUTIONS FOR AGRICULTURE PROBLEMS 



39 



to know how highly anything "pedestrian" is regarded, try walking along the 
edge of a busy highway; you will see that you are regarded mainly as an 
obstruction to the progress of greater power and velocity. The less power 
and velocity a thing has, the more "pedestrian" it is. A plow with one bot- 
tom is, as a matter of course, more "pedestrian" than a plow with eight bot- 
toms; the quality of use is not recognized as an issue. The hand laborers are 
thus to be eliminated from China's fields for the same reason that we now 
build housing developments without sidewalks: The pedestrian, not being 
allowed for, is not allowed. By the use of this term, the Secretary ignores the 
issue of the quality of work on the one hand, and on the other hand the 
issue of social values and aims. Is field work necessarily improved when 
done with machines instead of people? And is a worker necessarily 
improved by being replaced by a machine? Does a worker invariably work 
better, more ably, with more interest and satisfaction, when his power is 
mechanically magnified? And is a worker better off working at a "pedes- 
trian" farm task or unemployed in an urban ghetto? In which instance is his 
country better off? 

I have belabored Secretary Bergland's statement at such length not 
because it is so odd, but because it is so characteristic of the dominant 
American approach to agriculture. He is using— unconsciously, I suspect - 
the language of agricultural industrialism, which fails to solve agricultural 
problems correctly because it cannot understand or define them as agricul- 
tural problems. 

I will now try to define an approach to agriculture that is agricultural, that 
will lead to proper solutions, and that will, in consequence, safeguard and 
promote the health of the great unit of food production, which includes us 
all and all of our country. In order to do this I will deal with four problems, 
which seem to me inherent in the discipline of farming, and which are 
practical in the sense that their ultimate solutions cannot occur in public 
places— in organizations, in markets, or in policies-but only on farms. These 
are the problems of scale, of balance, of diversity, of quality. That these 
problems cannot be separated, and that no one of them can be solved with- 
out solving the others, testifies to their authenticity. 



40 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



1. The Problem of Scale. The identification of scale as a "problem" 
implies that things can be too big as well as too small, and I believe that 
this is so. Technology can grow to a size that is first undemocratic and then 
inhuman. It can grow beyond the control of individual human beings— and 
so, perhaps, beyond the control of human institutions. How large can a 
machine be before it ceases to serve people and begins to subjugate them? 

The size of landholdings is likewise a political fact. In any given region 
there is a farm size that is democratic, and a farm size that is plutocratic or 
totalitarian. A great danger to democracy now in the United States is the 
steep decline in the number of people who own farmland— or landed prop- 
erty of any kind. (According to a just-published report of the General 
Accounting Office, "Today, it is estimated that less than one-half of all 
farmland is owned by the operator.") Earl Butz has suggested that this is 
made up for by the increased numbers of people who own insurance poli- 
cies. But the value of insurance policies fluctuates with the value of money, 
whereas the real value of land never varies; it is always equal to the value of 
survival, of life. When this value is controlled by a wealthy or powerful 
minority, then democracy is reduced to mere governmental forms, easy to 
destroy or ignore. 

Moreover, in any given region there is a limit beyond which a farm out- 
grows the attention, affection, and care of a single owner. 

The size of fields is also a matter of agricultural concern. Fields can be 
too big to permit effective rotation of grazing, or to prevent erosion of land 
in cultivation. In general, the steeper the ground, the smaller should be the 
fields. On the steep slopes of the Andes, for instance, agriculture has sur- 
vived for thousands of years.This survival has obviously depended on hold- 
ing the soil in place, and the Andean peasants have an extensive method- 
ology of erosion control. Of all their means and methods, none is more 
important than the smallness of their fields— which is permitted by the 
smallness of their technology, most of the land still being worked by hand 
or with oxen. 

2The Problem of Balance. Finding the correct ratio between people 
and land, so that maintenance always equals production.This is obviously 
related to the problem of scale. In the correct solution to these problems, 



AGRICULTURE SOLUTIONS FOR AGRICULTURE PROBLEMS 



41 



such problems as soil erosion and soil compaction will be solved. 

But also each farm and each farmer must establish the proper ratio 
between plants and animals. This is the foundation of agricultural inde- 
pendence. In this balance of plants and animals the fertility cycle is kept 
complete, or as nearly complete as possible. Ideally, the farm would provide 
its own fertility. However, in commercial farming, when so many nutrients 
are shipped off the farm as food, it is necessary to return them to the farm 
in the form of composted "urban wastes"— sewage, garbage, etc. 

By studying the problem of balance, one discovers the carrying capaci- 
ty of a farm— that is, the amount it can produce without diminishing its 
ability to produce. 

When the problem of balance is solved, a farm's production becomes 
more or less constant. The farm will no longer be stocked or cultivated 
according to fluctuations of the market— which is not agriculture but an 
imitation, on the farm, of industrial economics. 

3. The Problem of Diversity. This is the only possible agricultural 
"backup system." On the farm it means not putting all the eggs in one bas- 
ket; it means— within the limits of nature, sense, and practicality— having as 
many kinds, as many species, as possible. 

In terms of our country's agriculture as a whole, too, it means the diver- 
sity of species. But it also means as many different kinds of good agriculture 
as possible: farms changing in kind, as necessary, from one location to 
another; but also truck farms and part-time farms near cities, to increase 
local self-sufficiency and independence; and home gardens everywhere, in 
the cities as well as in the country. 

4. The Problem of Quality. Quality, as I shall understand it here, is 
indistinguishable from health— bodily health, coming from good food, but 
also economic, political, cultural, and spiritual health. All these kinds of 
health are related. And I hope that my discussion of the other problems has 
begun to make clear how dependent health is on good work. 

Industrial agriculture has tended to look on the farmer as a "work- 
er"-a sort of obsolete but not yet dispensable machine— acting on the 
advice of scientists and economists. We have neglected the truth that a good 



42 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



farmer is a craftsman of the highest order, a kind of artist. It is the good 
work of good farmers-nothing else-that ensures a sufficiency of food over 
the long term. 

Ignoring that, industrial economics has encouraged poor work on the 
farm. I believe that it has done so because poor work can be easily priced. 
Since poor work lasts only a short time, the money value of its whole life 
can be readily calculated. Good work, which in fact or influence endures 
beyond the foresight of economists, can be valued but not priced, because 
its worth is incalculable. I am talking about the difference, say, between a 
wire fence and a stone wall, or between any gasoline engine and any good 
breed of livestock. 

I am more and more convinced that the only guarantee of quality in 
practice lies in the subsistence principle— that is, in the use of the product 
by the producer— a principle depreciated virtually out of existence by indus- 
trial agriculture. Indeed, it is sometimes offered as one of the benefits of 
industrial agriculture that farm families now patronize the supermarkets 
just like city people. On the other hand, it can be well argued that people 
who use their own products will be as concerned for quality as for quanti- 
ty, whereas people who produce exclusively for the market will be mainly 
interested in quantity. 

It will be noticed that production is not on my list of problems. The 
reason is that if the four problems I have dealt with are properly solved, pro- 
duction will not be a problem. Good production is merely the result of 
good farming. 



A Defense of the Family Farm 



(1986) 



DEFENDING THE FAMILY farm is like defending the Bill of Rights or the 
Sermon on the Mount or Shakespeare's plays. One is amazed at the 
necessity for defense, and yet one agrees gladly, knowing that the family 
farm is both eminently defensible and a part of the definition of one's own 
humanity. But having agreed to this defense, one remembers uneasily that 
there has been a public clamor in defense of the family farm throughout all 
the years of its decline— that, in fact, "the family farm" has become a politi- 
cal catchword, like democracy and Christianity, and much evil has been 
done in its name. 

Several careful distinctions are therefore necessary. What I shall mean 
by the term "family farm" is a farm small enough to be farmed by a family 
and one that is farmed by a family, perhaps with a small amount of hired 
help. I shall not mean a farm that is owned by a family and worked by other 
people. The family farm is both the home and the workplace of the family 
that owns it. 

By the verb "farm," I do not mean just the production of marketable 
crops but also the responsible maintenance of the health and usability of 
the place while it is in production. A family farm is one that is properly 
cared for by its family. 

Furthermore, the term "family farm" implies longevity in the connec- 
tion between family and farm. A family farm is not a farm that a family has 
bought on speculation and is only occupying and using until it can be prof- 



43 



44 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



itably sold. Neither, strictly speaking, is it a farm that a family has newly 
bought, though, depending on the intentions of the family, we may be able 
to say that such a farm is potentially a family farm. This suggests that we 
may have to think in terms of ranks or degrees of family farms. A farm that 
has been in the same family for three generations may rank higher as a fam- 
ily farm than a farm that has been in a family only one generation; it may 
have a higher degree of familiness or familiarity than the one-generation 
farm. Such distinctions have a practical usefulness to the understanding of 
agriculture, and, as I hope to show, there are rewards of longevity that do 
not accrue only to the family farm. 

I mentioned the possibility that a family farm might use a small 
amount of hired help. This greatly complicates matters, and I wish it were 
possible to say, simply, that a family farm is farmed with family labor. But 
it seems important to allow for the possibility of supplementing family 
labor with wagework or some form of sharecropping. Not only may family 
labor become insufficient as a result, say, of age or debility but also an equi- 
table system of wage earning or sharecropping would permit unpropertied 
families to earn their way to farm ownership. The critical points, in defin- 
ing "family farm," are that the amount of nonfamily labor should be small 
and that it should supplement, not replace, family labor. On a family farm, 
the family members are workers, not overseers. If a family on a family farm 
does require supplementary labor, it seems desirable that the hired help 
should live on the place and work year-round; the idea of a family farm is 
jeopardized by supposing that the farm family might be simply the 
guardians or maintainers of crops planted and harvested by seasonal work- 
ers. These requirements, of course, imply both small scale and diversity. 

Finally, I think we must allow for the possibility that a family farm 
might be very small or marginal and that it might not entirely support its 
family. In such cases, though the economic return might be reduced, the 
values of the family-owned and family-worked small farm are still available 
both to the family and to the nation. 

The idea of the family farm, as I have just defined it, is conformable in 
everyway to the idea of good farming-that is, farming that does not destroy 
either farmland or farm people.The two ideas may, in fact, be inseparable. 



A DEFENSE OF THE FAMILY FARM 



45 



If family farming and good farming are as nearly synonymous as I suspect 
they are, that is because of a law that is well understood, still, by most farm- 
ers but that has been ignored in the colleges, offices, and corporations of 
agriculture for thirty-five or forty years. The law reads something like this: 
Land that is in human use must be lovingly used; it requires intimate 
knowledge, attention, and care. 

The practical meaning of this law (to borrow an insight from Wes 
Jackson is that there is a ratio between eyes and acres, between farm size 
and farm hands, that is correct. We know that this law is unrelenting— that, 
for example, one of the meanings of our current high rates of soil erosion 
is that we do not have enough farmers; we have enough farmers to use the 
land but not enough to use it and protect it at the same time. 

In this law, which is not subject to human repeal, is the justification of 
the small, family-owned, family-worked farm, for this law gives a preemi- 
nent and irrevocable value to familiarity, the family life that alone can prop- 
erly connect a people to a land. This connection, admittedly, is easy to sen- 
timentalize, and we must be careful not to do so.We all know that small 
family farms can be abused because we know that sometimes they have 
been; nevertheless, it is true that familiarity tends to mitigate and to correct 
abuse. A family that has farmed land through two or three generations will 
possess not just the land but a remembered history of its own mistakes and 
of the remedies of those mistakes. It will know not just what it can do, what 
is technologically possible, but also what it must do and what it must not 
do; the family will have understood the ways in which it and the farm 
empower and limit one another. This is the value of longevity in landhold- 
ing: In the long term, knowledge and affection accumulate, and, in the 
long term, knowledge and affection pay.They do not just pay the family in 
goods and money; they also pay the family and the whole country in health 
and satisfaction. 

But the justifications of the family farm are not merely agricultural; 
they are political and cultural as well. The question of the survival of the 
family farm and the farm family is one version of the question of who will 
own the country, which is, ultimately, the question of who will own the 
people. Shall the usable property of our country be democratically divided, 



46 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



or not? Shall the power of property be a democratic power, or not? If many 
people do not own the usable property, then they must submit to the few 
who do own it.They cannot eat or be sheltered or clothed except in submis- 
sion. They will find themselves entirely dependent on money; they will find 
costs always higher, and money always harder to get. To renounce the prin- 
ciple of democratic property, which is the only basis of democratic liberty, 
in exchange for specious notions of efficiency or the economics of the so- 
called free market is a tragic folly. 

There is one more justification, among many, that I want to talk 
about— namely, that the small farm of a good farmer, like the small shop of 
a good craftsman or craftswoman, gives work a quality and a dignity that it 
is dangerous, both to the worker and the nation, for human work to go 
without. If using ten workers to make one pin results in the production of 
many more pins than the ten workers could produce individually, that is 
undeniably an improvement in production, and perhaps uniformity is a 
virtue in pins. But, in the process, ten workers have been demeaned; they 
have been denied the economic use of their minds; their work has become 
thoughtless and skill-less. Robert Heilbroner says that such "division of 
labor reduces the activity of labor to dismembered gestures." 

Eric Gill sees in this industrial dismemberment of labor a crucial dis- 
tinction between making and doing, and he describes "the degradation of the 
mind" that is the result of the shift from making to doing. This degrada- 
tion of the mind cannot, of course, be without consequences. One obvious 
consequence is the degradation of products.When workers' minds are 
degraded by loss of responsibility for what is being made, they cannot use 
judgment; they have no use for their critical faculties; they have no occa- 
sions for the exercise of workmanship, of workmanly pride. And the con- 
sumer is degraded by loss of the opportunity for qualitative choice.This is 
why we must now buy our clothes and immediately resew the buttons; it is 
why our expensive purchases quickly become junk. 

With industrialization has come a general depreciation of work. As the 
price of work has gone up, the value of it has gone down, until it is now so 
depressed that people simply do not want to do it anymore. We can say 
without exaggeration that the present national ambition of the United 



A DEFENSE OF THE FAMILY FARM 



47 



States is unemployment. People live for quitting time, for weekends, for 
vacations, and for retirement; moreover, this ambition seems to be class- 
less, as true in the executive suites as on the assembly lines. One works not 
because the work is necessary, valuable, useful to a desirable end, or 
because one loves to do it, but only to be able to quit-a condition that a 
saner time would regard as infernal, a condemnation. This is explained, of 
course, by the dullness of the work, by the loss of responsibility for, or cred- 
it for, or knowledge of the thing made. What can be the status of the work- 
ing small farmer in a nation whose motto is a sigh of relief: "Thank God 
it's Friday"? 

But there is an even more important consequence: By the dismem- 
berment of work, by the degradation of our minds as workers, we are 
denied our highest calling, for, as Gill says, "every man is called to give love 
to the work of his hands. Every man is called to be an artist." The small 
family farm is one of the last places-they are getting rarer every day— where 
men and women (and girls and boys, too) can answer that call to be an 
artist, to learn to give love to the work of their hands. It is one of the last 
places where the maker— and some farmers still do talk about "making the 
crops"— is responsible, from start to finish, for the thing made. This certain- 
ly is a spiritual value, but it is not for that reason an impractical or uneco- 
nomic one. In fact, from the exercise of this responsibility, this giving of 
love to the work of the hands, the farmer, the farm, the consumer, and the 
nation all stand to gain in the most practical ways: They gain the means of 
life, the goodness of food, and the longevity and dependability of the 
sources of food, both natural and cultural. The proper answer to the spiri- 
tual calling becomes, in turn, the proper fulfillment of physical need. 

THE FAMILY FARM, then, is good, and to show that it is good is easy. Those 
who have done most to destroy it have, I think, found no evil in it. But, if a 
good thing is failing among us, pretty much without being argued against 
and pretty much without professed enemies, then we must ask why it should 
fail. I have spent years trying to answer this question, and, while I am sure of 
some answers, I am also sure that the complete answer will be hard to come 
by because the complete answer has to do with who and what we are as a peo- 
ple; the fault lies in our identity and therefore will be hard for us to see. 



48 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



However, we must try to see, and the best place to begin may be with 
the fact that the family farm is not the only good thing that is failing among 
us.The family farm is failing because it belongs to an order of values and a 
kind of life that are failing. We can only find it wonderful, when we put our 
minds to it, that many people now seem willing to mount an emergency 
effort to "save the family farm" who have not yet thought to save the fami- 
ly or the community, the neighborhood schools or the small local business- 
es, the domestic arts of household and homestead, or cultural and moral 
tradition— all of which are also failing, and on all of which the survival of 
the family farm depends. 

The family farm is failing because the pattern it belongs to is failing, 
and the principal reason for this failure is the universal adoption, by our 
people and our leaders alike, of industrial values, which are based on three 
assumptions: 

1. That value equals price— that the value of a farm, for example, is what- 
ever it would bring on sale, because both a place and its price are 
"assets." There is no essential difference between farming and selling a 
farm. 

2. That all relations are mechanical. That a farm, for example, can be used 
like a factory, because there is no essential difference between a farm 
and a factory. 

3. That the sufficient and definitive human motive is competitiveness- 
that a community, for example, can be treated like a resource or a mar- 
ket, because there is no difference between a community and a resource 
or a market. 

The industrial mind is a mind without compunction; it simply accepts that 
people, ultimately, will be treated as things and that things, ultimately, will 
be treated as garbage. 

Such a mind is indifferent to the connections, which are necessarily 
both practical and cultural, between people and land; which is to say that 
it is indifferent to the fundamental economy and economics of human life. 
Our economy is increasingly abstract, increasingly a thing of paper, unable 
either to describe or to serve the real economy that determines whether or 



A DEFENSE OF THE FAMILY FARM 



49 



not people will eat and be clothed and sheltered. And it is this increasing- 
ly false or fantastical economy that is invoked as a standard of national 
health and happiness by our political leaders. 

That this so-called economy can be used as a universal standard can 
only mean that it is itself without standards. Industrial economists cannot 
measure the economy by the health of nature, for they regard nature as sim- 
ply a source of "raw materials." They cannot measure it by the health of peo- 
ple, for they regard people as "labor" (that is, as tools or machine parts) or 
as "consumers." They can measure the health of the economy only in sums 
of money. 

Here we come to the heart of the matter— the absolute divorce that the 
industrial economy has achieved between itself and all ideals and standards 
outside itself. It does this, of course, by arrogating to itself the status of pri- 
mary reality. Once that is established, all its ties to principles of morality, 
religion, or government necessarily fall slack. 

But a culture disintegrates when its economy disconnects from its gov- 
ernment, morality, and religion. If we are dismembered in our economic 
life, how can we be members in our communal and spiritual life? We 
assume that we can have an exploitive, ruthlessly competitive, profit-for- 
profit's-sake economy, and yet remain a decent and a democratic na- tion, 
as we still apparently wish to think ourselves. This simply means that our 
highest principles and standards have no practical force or influence and 
are reduced merely to talk. 

That this is true was acknowledged by William Safire in a recent col- 
umn, in which he declared that our economy is driven by greed and that 
greed, therefore, should no longer count as one of the seven deadly sins. 
"Greed," he said, "is finally being recognized as a virtue . . . the best engine 
of betterment known to man." It is, moreover, an agricultural virtue: "The 
cure for world hunger is the driving force of Greed." Such statements 
would be possible only to someone who sees the industrial economy as the 
ultimate reality. Mr. Safire attempts a disclaimer, perhaps to maintain his 
status as a conservative: "I hold no brief for Anger, Envy, Lust, Gluttony, 
Pride or Sloth." But this is not a cat that can be let only partly out of the 
bag. In fact, all seven of the deadly sins are "driving forces" of this econo- 



50 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



my, as its advertisements and commercials plainly show. 

As a nation, then, we are not very religious and not very democratic, 
and that is why we have been destroying the family farm for the last forty 
years— along with other small local economic enterprises of all kinds. We 
have been willing for millions of people to be condemned to failure and 
dispossession by the workings of an economy utterly indifferent to any 
claims they may have had either as children of God or as citizens of a 
democracy. "That's the way a dynamic economy works," we have said. We 
have said, "Get big or get out." We have said, "Adapt or die." And we have 
washed our hands of them. 

THROUGHOUT THIS PERIOD of drastic attrition on the farm, we supposedly 
have been "subsidizing agriculture," but, as Wes Jackson has pointed out,6 
this is a misstatement. What we have actually been doing is using the farm- 
ers to launder money for the agribusiness corporations, which have con- 
trolled both their supplies and their markets, while the farmers have over- 
produced and been at the mercy of the markets. The result has been that 
the farmers have failed by the millions, and the agribusiness corporations 
have prospered-or they prospered until the present farm depression, when 
some of them have finally realized that, after all, they are dependent on 
their customers, the farmers. 

Throughout this same desperate time, the colleges of agriculture, the 
experiment stations, and the extension services have been working under 
their old mandate to promote "a sound and prosperous agriculture and 
rural life," to "aid in maintaining an equitable balance between agricul- 
ture and other segments of the economy," to contribute "to the establish- 
ment and maintenance of a permanent and effective agricultural indus- 
try," and to help "the development and improvement of the rural home 
and rural life." 

That the land-grant system has failed this commission is, by now, obvi- 
ous. I am aware that there are many individual professors, scientists, and 
extension workers whose lives have been dedicated to the fulfillment of this 
commission and whose work has genuinely served the rural home and 
rural life. But, in general, it can no longer be denied that the system as a 
whole has failed. One hundred and twenty-four years after the Morrill Act, 



A DEFENSE OF THE FAMILY FARM 



51 



ninety-nine years after the Hatch Act, seventy-two years after the Smith- 
Lever Act, the "industrial classes" are not liberally educated, agriculture and 
rural life are not sound or prosperous or permanent, and there is no equi- 
table balance between agriculture and other segments of the economy. 
Anybody's statistics on the reduction of the farm population, on the decay 
of rural communities, on soil erosion, soil and water pollution, water short- 
ages, and farm bankruptcies tell indisputably a story of failure. 

This failure cannot be understood apart from the complex alle- 
giances between the land-grant system and the aims, ambitions, and val- 
ues of the agribusiness corporations. The willingness of land-grant pro- 
fessors, scientists, and extension experts to serve as state-paid researchers 
and traveling salesmen for those corporations has been well documented 
and is widely known. 

The reasons for this state of affairs, again, are complex. I have already 
given some of them; I don't pretend to know them all. But I would like to 
mention one that I think is probably the most telling: that the offices of 
the land-grant complex, like the offices of the agricultural bureaucracy, 
have been looked upon by their aspirants and their occupants as a means 
not to serve farmers, but to escape farming. Over and over again, one hears 
the specialists and experts of agriculture introduced as "old farm boys" who 
have gone on (as is invariably implied) to better things.The reason for this 
is plain enoughThe life of a farmer has characteristically been a fairly hard 
one, and the life of a college professor or professional expert has character- 
istically been fairly easy. Farmers— working family farmers— do not have 
tenure, business hours, free weekends, paid vacations, sabbaticals, and 
retirement funds; they do not have professional status. 

The direction of the career of agricultural professionals is, typically, 
not toward farming or toward association with farmers. It is "upward" 
through the hierarchy of a university, a bureau, or an agribusiness corpo- 
ration. They do not, like Cincinnatus, leave the plow to serve their people 
and return to the plow. They leave the plow, simply, for the sake of leaving 
the plow. 

This means that there has been for several decades a radical discon- 
nection between the land-grant institutions and the farms, and this dis- 



52 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



connection has left the land-grant professionals free to give bad advice; 
indeed, if they can get this advice published in the right place, from the 
standpoint of their careers it does not matter whether their advice is good 
or not. 

For example, after years of milk glut, when dairy farmers are every- 
where threatened by their surplus production, university experts are still 
working to increase milk production and still advising farmers to cull their 
least productive cows-apparently oblivious both of the possible existence 
of other standards of judgment and of the fact that this culling of the least 
productive cows is, ultimately, the culling of the smaller farmers. 

Perhaps this could be dismissed as human frailty or inevitable bureau- 
cratic blundering— except that the result is damage, caused by people who 
probably would not have given such advice if they were themselves in a 
position to suffer from it. Serious responsibilities are undertaken by public 
givers of advice, and serious wrong is done when the advice is bad. Surely 
a kind of monstrosity is involved when tenured professors with protected 
incomes recommend or even tolerate Darwinian economic policies for 
farmers, or announce (as one university economist after another has done) 
that the failure of so-called inefficient farmers is good for agriculture and 
good for the country. They see no inconsistency, apparently, between their 
own protectionist economy and the "free market" economy that they recom- 
mend to their supposed constituents, to whom the "free market" has 
proved, time and again, to be fatal. Nor do they see any inconsistency, 
apparently, between the economy of a university, whose sources, like those 
of any tax-supported institution, are highly diversified, and the extremely 
specialized economies that they have recommended to their farmer-con- 
stituents.These inconsistencies nevertheless exist, and they explain why, so 
far, there has been no epidemic of bankruptcies among professors of agri- 
cultural economics. 

These, of course, are simply instances of the notorious discrepancy 
between theory and practice. But this discrepancy need not exist, or it need 
not be so extreme, in the colleges of agriculture.The answer to the problem 
is simply that those who profess should practice. Or at least a significant 
percentage of them should. This is, in fact, the rule in other colleges and 



A DEFENSE OF THE FAMILY FARM 



53 



departments of the university. A professor of medicine who was no doctor 
would readily be seen as an oddity; so would a law professor who could not 
try a case; so would a professor of architecture who could not design a 
building. What, then, would be so strange about an agriculture professor 
who would be, and who would be expected to be, a proven farmer? 

BUT IT WOULD be wrong, I think, to imply that the farmers are merely the 
victims of their predicament and share none of the blame. In fact, they, 
along with all the rest of us, do share the blame, and their first hope of sur- 
vival is in understanding that they do. 

Farmers, as much as any other group, have subscribed to the indus- 
trial fantasies that I listed earlier: that value equals price, that all relations 
are mechanical, and that competitiveness is a proper and sufficient mo- 
tive. Farmers, like the rest of us, have assumed, under the tutelage of peo- 
ple with things to sell, that selfishness and extravagance are merely normal. 
Like the rest of us, farmers have believed that they might safely live a life 
prescribed by the advertisers of products, rather than the life required by 
fundamental human necessities and responsibilities. 

One could argue that the great breakthrough of industrial agriculture 
occurred when most farmers became convinced that it would be better to 
own a neighbor's farm than to have a neighbor, and when they became will- 
ing, necessarily at the same time, to borrow extravagant amounts of money. 
They thus violated the two fundamental laws of domestic or community 
economy:You must be thrifty and you must be generous; or, to put it in a 
more practical way, you must be (within reason) independent, and you 
must be neighborly. With that violation, farmers became vulnerable to 
everything that has intended their ruin. 

An economic program that encourages the unlimited growth of in- 
dividual holdings not only anticipates but actively proposes the failure of 
many people. Indeed, as our antimonopoly laws testify, it proposes the fail- 
ure, ultimately, of all but one. It is a fact, I believe, that many people have 
now lost their farms and are out of farming who would still be in place had 
they been willing for their neighbors to survive along with themselves. In 
light of this, we see that the machines, chemicals, and credit that farmers 
have been persuaded to use as "labor savers" have, in fact, performed as 



54 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



neighbor replacers. And whereas neighborhood tends to work as a service 
free to its members, the machines, chemicals, and credit have come at a 
cost set by people who were not neighbors. 

THAT IS A description of the problem of the family farm, as I see it. It is a 
dangerous problem, but I do not think it is hopeless. On the contrary, a 
number of solutions to the problem are implied in my description of it. 
What, then, can be done? 

The most obvious, the most desirable, solution would be to secure that 
"equitable balance between agriculture and other segments of the econo- 
my" that is one of the stated goals of the Hatch Act. To avoid the intrica- 
cies of the idea of "parity," which we inevitably think of here, I will just say 
that the price of farm products, as they leave the farm, should be on a par 
with the price of those products that the farmer must buy. 

In order to achieve this with minimal public expense, we must control 
agricultural production; supply must be adjusted to demand. Obviously 
this is something that individual farmers, or individual states, cannot do 
for themselves; it is a job that belongs appropriately to the federal govern- 
ment. As a governmental function, it is perfectly in keeping with the ideal, 
everywhere implicit in the originating documents of our government, that 
the small have a right to certain protections from the great. We have, with- 
in limits that are obvious and reasonable, the right to be small farmers or 
small businessmen or -women, just as, or perhaps insofar as, we have a right 
to life, liberty, and prosperity. The individual citizen is not to be victimized 
by the rich any more than by the powerful. When Marty Strange writes, "To 
the extent that only the exceptional succeed, the system fails," he is eco- 
nomically and agriculturally sound, but he is also speaking directly from 
American political tradition. 

The plight of the family farm would be improved also by other govern- 
mental changes— for example, in policies having to do with taxation and 
credit. 

Our political problem, of course, is that farmers are neither numerous 
enough nor rich enough to be optimistic about government help. The gov- 
ernment tends, rather, to find their surplus production useful and their 



A DEFENSE OF THE FAMILY FARM 



55 



economic failure ideologically desirable. Thus, it seems to me that we 
must concentrate on those things that farmers and farming communities 
can do for themselves— striving in the meantime for policies that would be 
desirable. 

It may be that the gravest danger to farmers is their inclination to look 
to the government for help, after the agribusiness corporations and the 
universities (to which they have already looked) have failed them. In the 
process, they have forgotten how to look to themselves, to their farms, to 
their families, to their neighbors, and to their tradition. 

Marty Strange has written also of his belief "that commercial agricul- 
ture can survive within pluralistic American society, as we know it— if [my 
emphasis] the farm is rebuilt on some of the values with which it is popu- 
larly associated: conservation, independence, self-reliance, family, and com- 
munity. To sustain itself, commercial agriculture will have to reorganize its 
social and economic structure as well as its technological base and produc- 
tion methods in a way that reinforces these values." I agree. Those are the 
values that offer us survival, not just as farmers, but as human beings. And 
I would point out that the transformation that Marty is proposing cannot 
be accomplished by the governments, the corporations, or the universities; 
if it is to be done, the farmers themselves, their families, and their neigh- 
bors will have to do it. 

What I am proposing, in short, is that farmers find their way out of the 
gyp joint known as the industrial economy. 

The first item on the agenda, I suggest, is the remaking of the rural 
neighborhoods and communities. The decay or loss of these has demon- 
strated their value; we find, as we try to get along without them, that they 
are worth something to us-spiritually, socially, and economically. And we 
hear again the voices out of our cultural tradition telling us that to have 
community, people don't need a "community center" or "recreational facil- 
ities" or any of the rest of the paraphernalia of "community improvement" 
that is always for sale. Instead, they need to love each other, trust each 
other, and help each other.That is hard. All of us know that no communi- 
ty is going to do those things easily or perfectly, and yet we know that there 
is more hope in that difficulty and imperfection than in all the neat instruc- 



56 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



tions for getting big and getting rich that have come out of the universities 
and the agribusiness corporations in the past fifty years. 

Second, the farmers must look to their farms and consider the losses, 
human and economic, that may be implicit in the way those farms are 
structured and used. If they do that, many of them will understand how 
they have been cheated by the industrial orthodoxy of competition— how 
specialization has thrown them into competition with other farmer-special- 
ists, how bigness of scale has thrown them into competition with neighbors 
and friends and family, how the consumer economy has thrown them into 
competition with themselves. 

If it is a fact that for any given farm there is a ratio between people and 
acres that is correct, there are also correct ratios between dependence and 
independence and between consumption and production. For a farm fam- 
ily, a certain degree of independence is possible and is desirable, but no 
farmer and no family can be entirely independent. A certain degree of 
dependence is inescapable; whether or not it is desirable is a question of 
who is helped by it. If a family removes its dependence from its neighbors 
-if, indeed, farmers remove their dependence from their families— and give 
it to the agribusiness corporations (and to moneylenders), the chances are, 
as we have seen, that the farmers and their families will not be greatly 
helped. This suggests that dependence on family and neighbors may con- 
stitute a very desirable kind of independence. 

It is clear, in the same way, that a farm and its family cannot be only 
productive; there must be some degree of consumption. This, also, is 
inescapable; whether or not it is desirable depends on the ratio. If the farm 
consumes too much in relation to what it produces, then the farm family 
is at the mercy of its suppliers and is exposed to dangers to which it need 
not be exposed. When, for instance, farmers farm on so large a scale that 
they cannot sell their labor without enormous consumption of equipment 
and supplies, then they are vulnerable. I talked to an Ohio farmer recently 
who cultivated his corn crop with a team of horses. He explained that, 
when he was plowing his corn, he was selling his labor and that of his team 
(labor fueled by the farm itself and, therefore, very cheap) rather than buy- 
ing herbicides. His point was simply that there is a critical difference 



A DEFENSE OF THE FAMILY FARM 



57 



between buying and selling and that the name of this difference at the 
year's end ought to be net gain. 

Similarly, when farmers let themselves be persuaded to buy their food 
instead of grow it, they become consumers instead of producers and lose a 
considerable income from their farms. This is simply to say that there is a 
domestic economy that is proper to the farming life and that it is different 
from the domestic economy of the industrial suburbs. 

FINALLY, I WANT to say that I have not been talking from speculation but 
from proof. I have had in mind throughout this essay the one example 
known to me of an American community of small family farmers who have 
not only survived but thrived during some very difficult years: I mean the 
Amish. I do not recommend, of course, that all farmers should become 
Amish, nor do I want to suggest that the Amish are perfect people or that 
their way of life is perfect. What I want to recommend are some Amish 
principles: 

1. They have preserved their families and communities. 

2. They have maintained the practices of neighborhood. 

3. They have maintained the domestic arts of kitchen and garden, house- 
hold and homestead. 

4. They have limited their use of technology so as not to displace or alien- 
ate available human labor or available free sources of power (the sun, 
wind, water, and so on). 

5. They have limited their farms to a scale that is compatible both with the 
practice of neighborhood and with the optimum use of low-power tech- 
nology. 

6. By the practices and limits already mentioned, they have limited their 
costs. 

7. They have educated their children to live at home and serve their com- 
munities. 

8. They esteem farming as both a practical art and a spiritual discipline. 



58 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



These principles define a world to be lived in by human beings, not a world 
to be exploited by managers, stockholders, and experts. 

Notes 

1. In conversation. 

2. Robert Heilbroner, "The Art of Work," Occasional Paper of the Council of Scholars 
(Washington, D.C.: Library of Congress, 1984), p. 20. 

3. Eric Gill, A Holy Tradition of Working (Suffolk, England: Golgonooza Press, 1983), p. 61. 

4. Ibid., p. 65. 

5. William Safire, "Make That Six Deadly Sins-A Re-examination Shows Greed to Be a 
Virtue," Courier-Journal (Louisville, Ky.), 7 Jan. 1986. 

6. In conversation. 

7. Hatch Act, United States Code, Section 361b. 

8. Marty Strange, "The Economic Structure of a Sustainable Agriculture," in Meeting the 
Expectations of the Land, ed. Wes Jackson, Wendell Berry, and Bruce Colman (San 
Francisco: North Point Press, 1984), p. 118. 

9. Ibid., p. 116. 



Let the Farm Judge 



(1997) 



TO ME, ONE of the most informative books on agriculture is British 
Sheep, published by the National Sheep Association of Britain. This 
book contains photographs and descriptions of sixty-five British sheep 
breeds and "recognized half-breds." I have spent a good deal of time look- 
ing at the pictures in this book and reading its breed descriptions, for I 
think that it represents one of the great accomplishments of agriculture. It 
makes a most impressive case for the intelligence and the judgment of 
British farmers over many centuries. 

What does it mean that an island not much bigger than Kansas or not 
much more than twice the size of Kentucky should have developed sixty or 
so breeds of sheep? It means that many thousands of farmers were paying 
the most discriminating attention, not only to their sheep, but also to the 
nature of their local landscapes and economies, for a long time.They were 
responding intelligently to the requirement of local adaptation.The result, 
when such an effort is carried on by enough intelligent farmers in the same 
region for a long time, is the development of a distinct breed that fits 
regional needs. Such local adaptation is the most important requirement 
for agriculture, wherever it occurs. If you are going to adapt your farming 
to a variety of landscapes, you are going to need a variety of livestock 
breeds, and a variety of types within breeds. 

The great diversity of livestock breeds, along with the great diversity 
of domestic plant varieties, can be thought of as a sort of vocabulary with 
which we may make appropriate responses to the demands of a great 



59 



60 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



diversity of localities. The goal of intelligent farmers, who desire the long- 
term success of farming, is to adapt their work to their places. Local adap- 
tation always requires reasonably correct answers to two questions: What 
is the nature— the need and the opportunity— of the local economy? and, 
What is the nature of the place? For example, it is a mistake to answer the 
economic question by plowing too steep a hillside, just as it is a mistake 
to answer the geographic or ecological question in a way that denies the 
farmer a living. 

Intelligent livestock breeders may find that, in practice, the two ques- 
tions become one: How can I produce the best meat at the lowest econom- 
ic and ecological cost? This question cannot be satisfactorily answered by 
the market, by the meatpacking industry, by breed societies, or by show ring 
judges. It cannot be answered satisfactorily by "animal science" experts, or 
by genetic engineers. It can only be answered satisfactorily by the farmer, 
and only if the farm, the place itself, is allowed to play a part in the process 
of selection. 

It goes without saying that the animal finally produced by any farm will 
be a product to some extent of the judgment of the farmer, the meatpack- 
er, the breed society, and the show ring judge. But the farm too must be 
permitted to make and enforce its judgment. If it is not permitted to do so, 
then there can be no local adaptation. And where there is no local adapta- 
tion, the farmer and the farm must pay significant penalties. 

In our era, because of commercial demand and the allure of the show 
ring, livestock breeding has tended to concentrate on the production of 
outstanding individual animals as determined by the ideal breed character- 
istics or the ideal carcass. In other words, a good brood cow or ewe is one 
that produces offspring that fit the prevailing show or commercial stan- 
dards. We don't worry enough about the cost of production, which would 
lead us directly to the issue of local adaptation. This sort of negligence, I 
think, could have been possible only in our time, when "cheap" fossil fuel 
has set the pattern in agriculture. Suffice it to say that much thoughtless- 
ness in livestock breeding has been subsidized by large checks paid to vet- 
erinarians and drug companies, and covered over by fat made of allegedly 
cheap corn. 



LET THE FARM JUDGE 



61 



Allegedly cheap fossil fuel, allegedly cheap transportation, and alleged- 
ly cheap corn and other feed grains have pushed agriculture toward unifor- 
mity, obscuring regional differences and, with them, the useful ness of 
locally adapted breeds, especially those that do well on forages. This is why 
there are now only a few dominant breeds, and why those breeds are large 
and grain-dependent. Now, for example, nearly all dairy cows are Holsteins, 
and the modern sheep is more than likely to have a black face and to be 
"big and tall." 

My friend Maury Telleen has pointed out to me that fifty years ago the 
Ayrshire was a popular dairy cow in New England and Kansas. The reason 
was her ability to make milk on the feed that was locally available; she did 
not require the optimal conditions and feedstuffs of Iowa or Illinois. She 
was, Maury says, "a cow that could 'get along.' " It is dangerous to assume 
that we have got beyond the need for farm animals that can "get along." 

If we assume that the inescapable goal of the farmer, especially in the 
present economy, must be to reduce costs, and, further, that costs are 
reduced by local adaptation, then we can begin to think about the prob- 
lems of livestock breeding by noting that corn, whatever its market price, is 
not cheap.What is cheap is grass— grazed grass-and where the grass grows 
determines the kind of animal needed to graze it. 

Our farm, in the lower Kentucky River valley, is mostly on hillsides. 
Heavy animals tend to damage hillsides, especially in winter. Our experi- 
ence with brood cows showed us that our farm needs sheep. It needs, in 
addition, sheep that can make their living by grazing coarse pasture on 
hillsides. And so in the fall of 1978 we bought six Border Cheviot ewes 
and a buck. At present we have about thirty ewes, and eventually we will 
have more. 

Our choice of breed was a good one. The Border Cheviot is a hill 
sheep, developed to make good use of such rough pasture as we have. 
Moreover, it can make good use of a little corn, and our farm is capable of 
producing a little corn. There have been problems, of course. Some of 
them have had to do with adapting ourselves to our breed.These have been 
important, but just as important have been the problems of adapting our 
flock to our farm. And those are the problems I want to discuss. 



62 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



There are now probably more Cheviots in the Midwest than else- 
where in the United States. For us, at any rate, the inevitable source of 
breeding stock has been the Midwest, and many of our problems have been 
traceable to that fact. What I am going to say implies no fault in the mid- 
western breeders, to whom we and our breed have an enormous debt. It is 
nevertheless true that, for a flock of sheep, living is easier in the prairie 
lands than on a Kentucky hillside. Just walking around on a hillside farm 
involves more strain and requires more energy, and the less fertile the land 
the farther a ewe will have to walk to fill her belly. Knees that might have 
remained sound on the gentle topography of Ohio or Iowa may become 
arthritic at our place. Also a ewe that would have twin lambs on a prairie 
farm may have only one on a hill farm. Similarly, a lamb will grow to 
slaughter weight more slowly where he has to allocate more energy to get- 
ting around. We once sold five yearling ewes to our friend Bob Willerton 
in Danvers, Illinois, where on their first lambing they produced eleven 
lambs. On our farm, they might have produced seven or eight. We have 
noticed the same difference with cull ewes that we have sent to our son's 
farm, which is less steep and more fertile than ours. 

Our farm, then, is asking for a ewe that can stay healthy, live long, 
breed successfully, have two lambs without assistance, and feed them well, 
in comparatively demanding circumstances. Experience has shown us that 
the Border Cheviot breed is capable of producing a ewe of this kind, but 
that it does not do so inevitably. In eighteen years, and out of a good many 
ewes bought or raised, we have identified so far only two ewe families (the 
female descendants of two ewes) that fairly dependably perform as we and 
our place require. 

The results of identifying and keeping the daughters of these ewe fam- 
ilies have been very satisfactory. This year they made up more than half of 
our bred ewes. Presumably because of that, our lambing percentage, which 
previously hovered around 150 percent, increased to 172 percent. This 
year also we reduced our winter hay-feeding by one month, not beginning 
until the first of February. Next year, we hope to feed no hay until we bring 
the ewes to the barn for lambing, which will be about the first of March. 1 
In livestock breeding it is always too early to brag, but of course we are 
encouraged. 



LET THE FARM JUDGE 



63 



In the language of Phillip Sponenberg and Carolyn Christman's excel- 
lent Conservation Breeding Handbook, we have employed "extensive" or "land- 
race" husbandry in managing a standardized breed. From the first, our 
flock has been "challenged by the environment"-required to live on what 
the place can most cheaply and sustainably provide, mainly pasture, with a 
minimum of attention and virtually no professional veterinary care. We 
give selenium injections to ewes and lambs and use a prudent amount of 
medication for parasites. We give no inoculations except for tetanus to the 
newborn lambs, and we have never trimmed a hoof. 

Until recently, and even now with ewes, our practice has been to buy 
bargains, animals that for one reason or another fell below the standards of 
the show ring. But I don't believe that our flock would have developed to 
our standards and requirements any faster if we had bought the champions 
out of the best shows every year. Some of the qualities we were after simply 
are not visible to show ring judges. 

I am not trying to argue that there is no good in livestock shows.The 
show ring is a useful tool; it is obviously instructive when good breeders 
bring good animals together for comparison. I am saying only that the show 
ring alone cannot establish and maintain adequate standards for livestock 
breeders.You could not develop locally adapted strains if your only stan- 
dards came from the show ring or from breed societies. 

The point is that, especially now when grain-feeding and confine- 
ment-feeding are so common, no American breeder should expect any 
breed to be locally adapted. Breeders should recognize that from the stand- 
point of local adaptation and cheap production, every purchase of a breed- 
ing animal is a gamble. A newly purchased ewe or buck may improve the 
performance of your flock on your farm or it may not. Good breeders will 
know, or they will soon find out, that theirs is not the only judgment that 
is involved. While the breeder is judging, the breeder's farm also is judging, 
enforcing its demands, and making selections. And this is as it should 
be.The judgment of the farm serves the breed, helping to preserve its genet- 
ic diversity. 

Because of the necessity of purchasing sires from time to time, the con- 
tinuity of the locally adapted flock must reside in the female lineages. 



64 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



Studying and preserving the most long-lived, thrifty, and productive ewe 
families are paramount. But this need not be laborious, for your farm will 
be selecting along with you.You pick the individuals that look good. This 
always implies that they have done well; and sooner or later you will know 
the look of "your kind," the kind that is apt to do well on your place.Your 
farm, however, will pick the ones that last. Even if you do not select at all, 
or if you select wrongly, a ewe that is not fitted to your farm will not con- 
tribute as many breeding animals to your flock as will a ewe that is fitted to 
your farm. 

It is generally acknowledged that a shepherd should know what he or 
she is doing. It is not so generally understood that the flock should know 
what it is doing-that is, how to live, thrive, and reproduce successfully on 
its home farm. But this knowledge, bred into the flock, is critical; it means 
meat from grass, at the lowest cost. 

Note 

1. We did so the next year, and have continued to do so, except in times of deep or crust- 
ed snow. We winter our ewes on a hillside that is ungrazed from early August until 
about Christmas. 



Energy in Agriculture 



(1979) 



I HAVE JUST BEEN rereading Donald Hall's lovely memoir, String Too Short 
to Be Saved. It is about the summers of his boyhood that the author 
spent on his grandparents' New Hampshire farm, from the late 1930s until 
the early 1950s.There are many good things in this book, but one of the 
best is its description of the life and economy of an old-time New England 
small farm. 

The farm of Kate and Wesley Wells, as their grandson knew it, was 
already a relic. It was what would now be called a "marginal farm" in moun- 
tainous country, in an agricultural community that had been dying since 
the Civil War.The farm produced food for the household and made a cash 
income from a small hand-milked herd of Holsteins and a flock of sheep. 
It furnished trees for firewood and maple syrup. The Wellses sent their 
daughters to school by the sale of timber from a woodlot.The farm and its 
household were "poor" by our present standards, taking in very little 
money— but spending very little too, and that is the most important thing 
about it. Its principle was thrift. Its needs were kept within the limits of its 
resources. 

This farm was ordered according to an old agrarian pattern which 
made it far more independent than modern farms built upon the pattern 
of industrial capitalism. And its energy economy was as independent as its 
money economy. The working energy of this farm came mainly from its 
people and from one horse. 



65 



66 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



Mr. Hall's memories inform us, more powerfully than any argument, 
that the life of Wesley and Kate Wells was a life worth living, decent though 
not easy; not adventurous or affluent, either— or not in our sense— but socia- 
ble, neighborly, and humane. They were intelligent, morally competent, 
upright, kind to people and animals, full of generous memories and good 
humor. From all that their grandson says of them, it is clear that his 
acquaintance with them and their place was profoundly enabling to his 
mind and his feelings. 

One cannot read this book— or I, anyhow, cannot— without asking how 
that sort of life escaped us, how it depreciated as a possibility so that we 
were able to give it up in order, as we thought, to "improve" ourselves. Mr. 
Hall makes it plain that farms like his grandparents' did not die out in New 
England necessarily because of bad farming, or because they did not pro- 
vide a viable way of life. They died for want of people with the motivation, 
the skill, the character, and the culture to keep them alive. They died, in 
other words, by a change in cultural value. Though it survived fairly intact 
until the middle of this century, Mr. Hall remembers that his grandparents' 
farm was surrounded by people and farms that had dwindled away because 
the human succession had been broken. It was no longer a place to come 
to, but a place to leave. 

At the time Mr. Hall writes about, something was gaining speed in our 
country that I think will seem more and more strange as time goes on. This 
was a curious set of assumptions, both personal and public, about 
"progress." If you could get into a profession, it was assumed, then of course 
you must not be a farmer; if you could move to the city, then you must not 
stay in the country; if you could farm more profitably in the corn belt than 
on the mountainsides of New England, then the mountainsides of New 
England must not be farmed. For years this set of assumptions was rarely 
spoken and more rarely questioned, and yet it has been one of the most 
powerful social forces at work in this country in modern times. 

But these assumptions could not accomplish much on their own. 
What gave them power, and made them able finally to dominate and re- 
shape our society, was the growth of technology for the production and use 
of fossil fuel energy.This energy could be made available to empower such 



ENERGY IN AGRICULTURE 67 



unprecedented social change because it was "cheap." But we were able to 
consider it "cheap" only by a kind of moral simplicity: the assumption that 
we had a "right" to as much of it as we could use. This was a "right" made 
solely by might. Because fossil fuels, however abundant they once were, 
were nevertheless limited in quantity and not renewable, they obviously did 
not "belong" to one generation more than another. We ignored the claims 
of posterity simply because we could, the living being stronger than the 
unborn, and so worked the "miracle" of industrial progress by the theft of 
energy from (among others) our children. 

That is the real foundation of our progress and our affluence. The rea- 
son that we are a rich nation is not that we have earned so much 
wealth-you cannot, by any honest means, earn or deserve so much.The rea- 
son is simply that we have learned, and become willing, to market and use 
up in our own time the birthright and livelihood of posterity. 

And so it is too simple to say that the "marginal" farms of New England 
were abandoned because of progress or because they were no longer pro- 
ductive or desirable as living places. They were given up for one very "prac- 
tical" reason: They did not lend themselves readily to exploitation by fossil 
fuel technology. Their decline began with the rise of steam power and the 
industrial economy after the Civil War; the coming of industrial agricul- 
ture after World War II finished them off. Industrial agriculture needs 
large holdings and large level fields. As the scale of technology grows, the 
small farms with small or steep fields are pushed farther and farther toward 
the economic margins and are finally abandoned. And so industrial agri- 
culture sticks itself deeper and deeper into a curious paradox: The larger its 
technology grows in order "to feed the world," the more potentially produc- 
tive "marginal" land it either ruins or causes to be abandoned. If the sweep- 
ing landscapes of Nebraska now have to be reshaped by computer and bull- 
dozer to allow the more efficient operation of big farm machines, then 
thousands of acres of the smaller-featured hill country of the eastern states 
must obviously be considered "unfarmable." Or so the industrialists of agri- 
culture have ruled. 

And so energy is not just fuel. It is a powerful social and cultural influ- 
ence. The kind and quantity of the energy we use determine the kind and 



68 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



quality of the life we live. Our conversion to fossil fuel energy subjected 
society to a sort of technological determinism, shifting population and val- 
ues according to the new patterns and values of industrialization. Rural 
wealth and materials and rural people were caught within the gravitational 
field of the industrial economy and flowed to the cities, from which com- 
paratively little flowed back in return. And so the human life of farmsteads 
and rural communities dwindled everywhere, and in some places perished. 

IF THE SHIFT to fossil fuel energy radically changed the life and the values of 
farm communities, it should be no surprise that it also radically changed 
our understanding of agriculture. Some figures from an article by Professor 
Mark D. Shaw help to show the nature of this change. The "food system," 
according to Professor Shaw, now uses 16.5 percent of all energy used in 
the United States. This 16.5 percent is used in the following ways: 

On-farm production - 3.0% 

Manufacturing - 4.9% 

Wholesale marketing — 0.5% 

Retail marketing - 0.8% 

Food preparation (in home) - 4.4% 

Food preparation (commercial) - 2.9% 

Apologists for industrial agriculture frequently stop with that first 
figure— showing that agriculture uses only a small amount of energy, rela- 
tively speaking, and that people hunting a cause of the "energy crisis" 
should therefore point their fingers elsewhere. The other figures, amount- 
ing to 13.5 percent of national energy consumption, are more interesting, 
for they suggest the way the food system has been expanded to make room 
for industrial enterprise. Between farm and home, producer and con- 
sumer, we have interposed manufacturers, a complex marketing structure, 
and food preparation. I am not sure how this last category differs from 
"manufacturing." And I would like to know what percentage of the energy 
budget goes for transportation, and whether or not Professor Shaw figured 
in the miles that people now drive to shop. The gist is nevertheless plain 
enough: The industrial economy grows and thrives by lengthening and 



ENERGY IN AGRICULTURE 69 



complicating the essential connection between producer and consumer. In 
a local food economy, dealing in fresh produce to be prepared in the home 
(thus eliminating transporters, manufacturers, packagers, preparers, etc.), 
the energy budget would be substantially lower, and we might have both 
cheaper food and higher earnings on the farm. 

But Professor Shaw provides another set of figures that is even more 
telling. These have to do with the "sources of energy for Pennsylvania agri- 
culture" (I don't think the significance would vary much from one state to 
another): 

Nuclear - 1% 
Coal - 5% 
Natural gas - 27% 
Petroleum - 67% 

And so we see that, though our agriculture may use relatively little fossil 
fuel energy, it is almost totally dependent on what it does use. It uses fossil 
fuel energy almost exclusively and uses it in competition with other users. 
And the sources of this energy are not renewable. 

This critical dependence on nonrenewable energy sources is the direct 
result of the industrialization of agriculture. Before industrialization, agri- 
culture depended almost exclusively on solar energy. Solar energy not only 
grew the plants, as it still does, but also provided the productive power of 
farms in the form of the work of humans and animals. This energy is 
derived and made available biologically, and it is recyclable. It is inex- 
haustible in the topsoil so long as good husbandry keeps the life cycle 
intact. 

This old sun-based agriculture was fundamentally alien to the indus- 
trial economy; industrial corporations could make relatively little profit 
from it. In order to make agriculture fully exploitable by industry it was 
necessary (in Barry Commoner's terms) to weaken "the farm's link to the 
sun" and to make the farmland a "colony" of the industrial corporations. 
The farmers had to be persuaded to give up the free energy of the sun in 
order to pay dearly for the machine-derived energy of the fossil fuels. 



70 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



Thus we have another example of a system artificially expanded for 
profit. The farm's originally organic, coherent, independent production 
system was expanded into a complex dependence on remote sources and 
on manufactured supplies. 

What happened, from a cultural point of view, was that machines were 
substituted for farmers, and energy took the place of skill. As farmers 
became more and more dependent on fossil fuel energy, a radical change 
occurred in their minds. Once focused on biology, the life and health of 
living things, their thinking now began to focus on technology and eco- 
nomics. Credit, for example, became as pressing an issue as the weather, for 
farmers had begun to climb the one-way ladder of survival by debt. Bigger 
machines required more land, and more land required yet bigger machines, 
which required yet more land, and on and on— the survivors climbing to 
precarious and often temporary success by way of machines and mortgages 
and the ruin of their neighbors. And so the farm became a "factory," where 
speed, "efficiency," and profitability were the main standards of perform- 
ance. These standards, of course, are industrial, not agricultural. 

The old solar agriculture, moreover, was time oriented. Timeliness was 
its virtue. One took pride in having the knowledge to do things at the right 
time. Industrial agriculture is space oriented. Its virtue is speed. One takes 
pride in being first. The right time, by contrast, could be late as well as 
early; the proof of the work was in its quality. 

The MOST IMPORTANT point I have to make is that once agriculture shifted 
its dependence from solar, biologically derived energy to machine-derived 
fossil fuel energy, it committed itself, as a matter of course, to several kinds 
of waste: 

1. The waste of solar energy, not just as motive power, but even as growing 
power. As landholdings become larger and the number of farmers 
smaller, more and more fields must go without cover crops, which 
means that for many days in the fall and early spring the sunlight on 
these fields is not captured in green leaves and so made useful to the 
soil and to people. It goes to waste. 

2. The waste of human energy and ability. Industrial agriculture replaces 



ENERGY IN AGRICULTURE 



71 



people with machines; the ability of millions of people to become skill- 
ful and to do work therefore comes to nothing. We now have millions 
on some kind of government support, grown useless and helpless, while 
our country becomes unhealthy and ugly for want of human work and 
care. And we have additional millions not on welfare who have grown 
almost equally useless and helpless for want of health. How much 
potentially useful energy do we now have stored in human belly fat? 
And what is it costing us, not only in medical bills, but in money spent 
on diets, drugs, and exercise machines? 

3. The waste of animal energy. I mean not just the abandonment of live 
horsepower, but the waste involved in confinement-feeding. Why use 
fossil fuel energy to bring food to grazing animals that are admirably 
designed to go get it themselves? 

4. The waste of soil and soil health. Because the number of farmers has 
now grown so small in proportion to the number of acres that must be 
farmed, it has been necessary to resort to all sorts of mechanical short- 
cuts. But shortcuts never have resulted in good work, and there is no 
reason to believe that they ever will. When a farmer must cover an enor- 
mous acreage within the strict limits of the seasons of planting and har- 
vest, speed necessarily becomes the first consideration. And so the 
machinery, not the land, becomes the focus of attention and the stan- 
dard of the work. Consequently, the fields get larger so as to require less 
turning, waterways are plowed out, and one sees less and less terracing 
and contour or strip plowing. And, as I mentioned above, less and less 
land is sowed in a cover crop; when such large acreages must be harvest- 
ed, there is no time for a fall seeding. The result is catastrophic soil ero- 
sion even in such "flat" states as Iowa. 

A problem related to soil waste is that of soil compaction. Part of the rea- 
son for this is that industrial agriculture reduces the humus in the soil, 
which becomes more cohesive and less porous as a result. Another reason 
is the use of heavier equipment, which becomes necessary, in the first 
place, because of soil compaction. But the main reason, I think, is again 
that we don't have enough farmers to farm the land properly. The industri- 
al farmer has so much land that he cannot afford to wait for "the right time" 



72 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



to work his fields. As long as the ground will support his equipment, he 
plows and harrows; the time is right for the work whenever the work is 
mechanically possible. It is commonplace now, wherever I have traveled in 
farm country, to see fields cut to pieces by deep wheel tracks. 

The final irony is that we are abusing our land in this way partly in 
order to correct our "balance of payments"-that is, in order to buy foreign 
petroleum. In the language of some "agribusiness" experts we are using 
"agridollars" to offset the drain of "petrodollars." We are, in effect, export- 
ing our topsoil in order to keep our tractors running. 

There is no question that you can cover a lot of ground with the big 
machines now on the market. A lot of people seem entranced by the power 
and speed of those machines, which the manufacturers love to refer to as 
"monsters" and "acre eaters." But the result is not farming; it is a process 
closely akin to mining. In what is left of the country communities, in 
earshot of the monster acre eaters of the "agribusinessmen," a lot of old 
farmers must be turning over in their graves. 



Conservationist and Agrarian 



(2002) 



I AM A CONSERVATIONIST and a farmer, a wilderness advocate and an 
agrarian. I am in favor of the world's wildness, not only because I like it, 
but also because I think it is necessary to the world's life and to our own. 
For the same reason, I want to preserve the natural health and integrity of 
the world's economic landscapes, which is to say that I want the world's 
farmers, ranchers, and foresters to live in stable, locally adapted, resource- 
preserving communities, and I want them to thrive. 

One thing that this means is that I have spent my life on two losing 
sides. As long as I have been conscious, the great causes of agrarianism and 
conservation, despite local victories, have suffered an accumulation of loss- 
es, some of them probably irreparable— while the third side, that of the 
land-exploiting corporations, has appeared to grow ever richer. I say 
"appeared" because I think their wealth is illusory. Their capitalism is 
based, finally, not on the resources of nature, which it is recklessly destroy- 
ing, but on fantasy. Not long ago I heard an economist say, "If the con- 
sumer ever stops living beyond his means, we'll have a recession. "And so 
the two sides of nature and the rural communities are being defeated by a 
third side that will eventually be found to have defeated itself. 

Perhaps in order to survive its inherent absurdity, the third side is as- 
serting its power as never before: by its control of politics, of public edu- 
cation, and of the news media; by its dominance of science; and by bio- 
technology, which it is commercializing with unprecedented haste and 
aggression in order to control totally the world's land-using economies and 



73 



74 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



its food supply. This massive ascendancy of corporate power over democrat- 
ic process is probably the most ominous development since the end of 
World War II, and for the most part "the free world" seems to be regarding 
it as merely normal. 

My sorrow in having been for so long on two losing sides has been com- 
pounded by knowing that those two sides have been in conflict, not only 
with their common enemy, the third side, but also, and by now almost con- 
ventionally, with each other. And I am further aggrieved in understanding 
that everybody on my two sides is deeply implicated in the sins and in the 
fate of the self-destructive third side. 

As a part of my own effort to think better, I decided not long ago that 
I would not endorse any more wilderness preservation projects that do not 
seek also to improve the health of the surrounding economic landscapes 
and human communities. One of my reasons is that I don't think we can 
preserve either wildness or wilderness areas if we can't preserve the eco- 
nomic landscapes and the people who use them.This has put me into dis- 
comfort with some of my conservation friends, but that discomfort only 
balances the discomfort I feel when farmers or ranchers identify me as an 
"environmentalist," both because I dislike the term and because I sympa- 
thize with farmers and ranchers. 

Whatever its difficulties, my decision to cooperate no longer in the sep- 
aration of the wild and the domestic has helped me to see more clearly the 
compatibility and even the coherence of my two allegiances. The dualism 
of domestic and wild is, after all, mostly false, and it is misleading. It has 
obscured for us the domesticity of the wild creatures. More important, it 
has obscured the absolute dependence of human domesticity upon the 
wildness that supports it and in fact permeates it. In suffering the now-com- 
mon accusation that humans are "anthropocentric" (ugly word), we forget 
that the wild sheep and the wild wolves are respectively ovicentric and 
lupocentric. The world, we may say, is wild, and all the creatures are home- 
makers within it, practicing domesticity: mating, raising young, seeking 
food and comfort. Likewise, though the wild sheep and the farm-bred 
sheep are in some ways unlike in their domesticities, we forget too easily 
that if the "domestic" sheep become too unwild, as some occasionally do, 



CONSERVATIONIST AND AGRARIAN 75 



they become uneconomic and useless: They have reproductive problems, 
conformation problems, and so on. Domesticity and wildness are in fact 
intimately connected. What is utterly alien to both is corporate industrial- 
ism—a displaced economic life that is without affection for the places where 
it is lived and without respect for the materials it uses. 

The question we must deal with is not whether the domestic and the 
wild are separate or can be separated; it is how, in the human economy, 
their indissoluble and necessary connection can be properly maintained. 

But to say that wildness and domesticity are not separate, and that we 
humans are to a large extent responsible for the proper maintenance of 
their relationship, is to come under a heavy responsibility to be practical. I 
have two thoroughly practical questions on my mind. 

The FIRST IS: Why should conservationists have a positive interest in, for 
example, farming? There are lots of reasons, but the plainest is: 
Conservationists eat.To be interested in food but not in food production 
is clearly absurd. Urban conservationists may feel entitled to be uncon- 
cerned about food production because they are not farmers. But they can't 
be let off so easily, for they all are farming by proxy. They can eat only if 
land is farmed on their behalf by somebody somewhere in some fashion. If 
conservationists will attempt to resume responsibility for their need to eat, 
they will be led back fairly directly to all their previous concerns for the wel- 
fare of nature. 

Do conservationists, then, wish to eat well or poorly? Would they like 
their food supply to be secure from one year to the next? Would they like 
their food to be free of poisons, antibiotics, alien genes, and other contam- 
inants? Would they like a significant portion of it to be fresh? Would they 
like it to come to them at the lowest possible ecological cost? The answers, 
if responsibly given, will influence production, will influence land use, will 
determine the configuration and the health of landscapes. 

If conservationists merely eat whatever the supermarket provides and 
the government allows, they are giving economic support to all-out indus- 
trial food production: to animal factories; to the depletion of soil, rivers, 
and aquifers; to crop monocultures and the consequent losses of biological 



76 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



and genetic diversity; to the pollution, toxicity, and overmedication that are 
the inevitable accompaniments of all-out industrial food production; to a 
food system based on long-distance transportation and the consequent 
waste of petroleum and the spread of pests and diseases; and to the divi- 
sion of the countryside into ever larger farms and ever larger fields receiv- 
ing always less human affection and human care. 

If, on the other hand, conservationists are willing to insist on having 
the best food, produced in the best way, as close to their homes as possible, 
and if they are willing to learn to judge the quality of food and food pro- 
duction, then they are going to give economic support to an entirely differ- 
ent kind of land use in an entirely different landscape. This landscape will 
have a higher ratio of caretakers to acres, of care to use. It will be at once 
more domestic and more wild than the industrial landscape. Can increas- 
ing the number of farms and farmers in an agricultural landscape enhance 
the quality of that landscape as wildlife habitat? Can it increase what we 
might call the wilderness value of that landscape? It can do so, and the 
determining factor would be diversity. Don't forget that we are talking 
about a landscape that is changing in response to an increase in local con- 
sumer demand for local food. Imagine a modern agricultural landscape 
devoted mainly to corn and soybeans and to animal factories. And then 
imagine its neighboring city developing a demand for good, locally grown 
food.To meet that demand, local farming would have to diversify. 

If that demand is serious, if it is taken seriously, if it comes from in- 
formed and permanently committed consumers, if it promises the neces- 
sary economic support, then that radically oversimplified landscape will 
change.The crop monocultures and animal factories will give way to the 
mixed farming of plants and animals. Pastured flocks and herds of meat 
animals, dairy herds, and poultry flocks will return, requiring, of course, 
pastures and hayfields. If the urban consumers would extend their com- 
petent concern for the farming economy to include the forest economy and 
its diversity of products, that would improve the quality and care, and 
increase the acreage, of farm woodlands. And we should not forget the pos- 
sibility that good farmers might, for their own instruction and pleasure, 
preserve patches of woodland unused. As the meadows and woodlands 
flourished in the landscape, so would the wild birds and animals. The 



CONSERVATIONIST AND AGRARIAN 77 



acreages devoted to corn and soybeans, grown principally as livestock feed 
or as raw materials for industry, would diminish in favor of the fruits and 
vegetables required by human dinner tables. 

As the acreage under perennial cover increased, soil erosion would 
decrease and the water-holding capacity of the soil would increase. Creeks 
and rivers would grow cleaner and their flow more constant. As farms 
diversified, they would tend to become smaller because complexity and 
work increase with diversity, and so the landscape would acquire more own- 
ers. As the number of farmers and the diversity of their farms increased, 
the toxicity of agriculture would decrease— insofar as agricultural chemicals 
are used to replace labor and to defray the biological costs of monoculture. 
As food production became decentralized, animal wastes would be dis- 
persed, and would be absorbed and retained in the soil as nutrients rather 
than flowing away as waste and as pollutants. The details of such a trans- 
formation could be elaborated almost endlessly. To make short work of it 
here, we could just say that a dangerously oversimplified landscape would 
become healthfully complex, both economically and ecologically. 

Moreover, since we are talking about a city that would be living in large 
measure from its local fields and forests, we are talking also about a local 
economy of decentralized, small, nonpolluting value-adding factories and 
shops that would be scaled to fit into the landscape with the least ecologi- 
cal or social disruption. And thus we can also credit to this economy an 
increase in independent small businesses, in self-employment, and a 
decrease in the combustible fuel needed for transportation and (I believe) 
for production. 

Such an economy is technically possible, there can be no doubt of that; 
we have the necessary methods and equipment. The capacity of nature to 
accommodate, and even to cooperate in, such an economy is also 
undoubtable; we have the necessary historical examples.This is not, from 
nature's point of view, a pipe dream. 

What is doubtable, or at least unproven, is the capacity of modern 
humans to choose, make, and maintain such an economy. For at least half 
a century we have taken for granted that the methods of farming could safe- 
ly be determined by the mechanisms of industry, and that the economies 



78 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



of farming could safely be determined by the economic interests of indus- 
trial corporations.We are now running rapidly to the end of the possibility 
of that assumption. The social, ecological, and even the economic costs 
have become too great, and the costs are still increasing, all over the world. 

Now we must try to envision an agriculture founded not on mechani- 
cal principles, but on the principles of biology and ecology. Sir Albert 
Howard and Wes Jackson have argued at length for such a change of stan- 
dards. If you want to farm sustainably, they have told us, then you have got 
to make your farming conform to the natural laws that govern the local 
ecosystem.You have got to farm with both plants and animals in as great a 
diversity as possible, you have got to conserve fertility, recycle wastes, keep 
the ground covered, and so on. Or, as J. Russell Smith put it seventy years 
ago, you have got to "fit the farming to the land"— not to the available tech- 
nology or the market, as important as those considerations are, but to the 
land. It is necessary, in short, to maintain a proper connection between the 
domestic and the wild.The paramount standard by which the work is to be 
judged is the health of the place where the work is done. 

But this is not a transformation that we can just drift into, as we drift 
in and out of fashions, and it is not one that we should wait to be forced 
into by large-scale ecological breakdown. It won't happen if a lot of peo- 
ple-consumers and producers, city people and country people, conserva- 
tionists and land users— don't get together deliberately to make it happen. 

Those are some of the reasons why conservationists should take an 
interest in farming and make common cause with good farmers. Now I 
must get on to the second of my practical questions. 

Why should FARMERS be conservationists? Or maybe I had better ask why 
are good farmers conservationists? The farmer lives and works in the meet- 
ing place of nature and the human economy, the place where the need for 
conservation is most obvious and most urgent. Farmers either fit their 
farming to their farms, conform to the laws of nature, and keep the natu- 
ral powers and services intact— or they do not. If they do not, then they 
increase the ecological deficit that is being charged to the future. (I had bet- 
ter admit that some farmers do increase the ecological deficit, but they are 
not the farmers I am talking about. I am not asking conservationists to sup- 



CONSERVATIONIST AND AGRARIAN 79 



port destructive ways of farming.) 

Good farmers, who take seriously their duties as stewards of Creation 
and of their land's inheritors, contribute to the welfare of society in more 
ways than society usually acknowledges, or even knows. These farmers pro- 
duce valuable goods, of course; but they also conserve soil, they conserve 
water, they conserve wildlife, they conserve open space, they conserve 
scenery. 

All that is merely what farmers ought to do. But since our present soci- 
ety's first standard in all things is profit and it loves to dwell on "econom- 
ic reality," I can't resist a glance at these good farmers in their economic 
circumstances, for these farmers will be poorly paid for the goods they 
produce, and for the services they render to conservation they will not be 
paid at all. Good farmers today may market products of high quality and 
perform well all the services I have listed, and still be unable to afford 
health insurance, and still find themselves mercilessly caricatured in the 
public media as rural simpletons, hicks, or rednecks. And then they hear 
the voices of the "economic realists": "Get big or get out. Sell out and go 
to town. Adapt or die." We have had fifty years of such realism in agricul- 
ture, and the result has been more and more large-scale monocultures and 
factory farms, with their ever larger social and ecological— and ultimately 
economic-costs. 

Why do good farmers farm well for poor pay and work as good stew- 
ards of nature for no pay, many of them, moreover, having no hope that 
their farms will be farmed by their children (for the reasons given) or that 
they will be farmed by anybody? 

Well, I was raised by farmers, have farmed myself, and have in turn 
raised two farmers-which suggests to me that I may know something 
about farmers, and also that I don't know very much. But over the years I 
along with a lot of other people have wondered, "Why do they do it?" Why 
do farmers farm, given their economic adversities on top of the many frus- 
trations and difficulties normal to farming? And always the answer is: 
"Love. They must do it for love." Farmers farm for the love of farming. 
They love to watch and nurture the growth of plants. They love to live in 
the presence of animals. They love to work outdoors. They love the weath- 



80 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



er, maybe even when it is making them miserable. They love to live where 
they work and to work where they live. If the scale of their farming is small 
enough, they like to work in the company of their children and with the 
help of their children. They love the measure of independence that farm 
life can still provide. I have an idea that a lot of farmers have gone to a lot 
of trouble merely to be self-employed, to live at least a part of their lives 
without a boss. 

And so the first thing farmers as conservationists must try to conserve 
is their love of farming and their love of independence. Of course they can 
conserve these things only by handing them down, by passing them on to 
their children, or to somebody's children. Perhaps the most urgent task for 
all of us who want to eat well and to keep eating is to encourage farm-raised 
children to take up farming. And we must recognize that this only can be 
done economically. Farm children are not encouraged by watching their 
parents take their products to market only to have them stolen at prices less 
than the cost of production. 

But farmers obviously are responsible for conserving much more than 
agrarian skills and attitudes. I have already told why farmers should be, as 
much as any conservationists, conservers of the wildness of the world— and 
that is their inescapable dependence on nature. Good farmers, I believe, 
recognize a difference that is fundamental between what is natural and 
what is man-made. They know that if you treat a farm as a factory and liv- 
ing creatures as machines, or if you tolerate the idea of "engineering" organ- 
isms, then you are on your way to something destructive and, sooner or 
later, too expensive. To treat creatures as machines is an error with large 
practical implications. 

Good farmers know too that nature can be an economic ally. Natural 
fertility is cheaper, often in the short run, always in the long run, than pur- 
chased fertility. Natural health, inbred and nurtured, is cheaper than phar- 
maceuticals and chemicals. Solar energy— if you know how to capture and 
use it: in grass, say, and the bodies of animals— is cheaper than petroleum. 
The highly industrialized factory farm is entirely dependent on "purchased 
inputs." The agrarian farm, well integrated into the natural systems that 
support it, runs to an economically significant extent on resources and sup- 



CONSERVATIONIST AND AGRARIAN 8 1 



plies that are free. 

It is now commonly assumed that when humans took to agriculture 
they gave up hunting and gathering. But hunting and gathering remained 
until recently an integral and lively part of my own region's traditional 
farming life. People hunted for wild game; they fished the ponds and 
streams; they gathered wild greens in the spring, hickory nuts and walnuts 
in the fall; they picked wild berries and other fruits; they prospected for 
wild honey. Some of the most memorable, and least regrettable, nights of 
my own youth were spent in coon hunting with farmers. There is no deny- 
ing that these activities contributed to the economy of farm households, 
but a further fact is that they were pleasures; they were wilderness pleasures, 
not greatly different from the pleasures pursued by conservationists and 
wilderness lovers. As I was always aware, my friends the coon hunters were 
not motivated just by the wish to tree coons and listen to hounds and lis- 
ten to each other, all of which were sufficiently attractive; they were coon 
hunters also because they wanted to be afoot in the woods at night. Most 
of the farmers I have known, and certainly the most interesting ones, have 
had the capacity to ramble about outdoors for the mere happiness of it, 
alert to the doings of the creatures, amused by the sight of a fox catching 
grasshoppers, or by the puzzle of wild tracks in the snow. 

As the countryside has depopulated and the remaining farmers have 
come under greater stress, these wilderness pleasures have fallen away. But 
they have not yet been altogether abandoned; they represent something 
probably essential to the character of the best farming, and they should be 
remembered and revived. 

Those, then, are some reasons why good farmers are conservationists, 
and why all farmers ought to be. 

WHAT I HAVE been trying to do is to define a congruity or community of 
interest between farmers and conservationists who are not farmers. To 
name the interests that these two groups have in common, and to observe, 
as I did at the beginning, that they also have common enemies, is to raise 
a question that is becoming increasingly urgent: Why don't the two groups 
publicly and forcefully agree on the things they agree on, and make an 
effort to cooperate? I don't mean to belittle their disagreements, which I 



82 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



acknowledge to be important. Nevertheless, cooperation is now necessary, 
and it is possible. If Kentucky tobacco farmers can meet with antismoking 
groups, draw up a set of "core principles" to which they all agree, and then 
support those principles, something of the sort surely could happen 
between conservationists and certain land-using enterprises: family farms 
and ranches, small-scale, locally owned forestry and forest products indus- 
tries, and perhaps others. Something of the sort, in fact, is beginning to 
happen, but so far the efforts are too small and too scattered. The larger 
organizations on both sides need to take an interest and get involved. 

If these two sides, which need to cooperate, have so far been at odds, 
what is the problem? The problem, I think, is economic. The small land 
users, on the one hand, are struggling so hard to survive in an economy 
controlled by the corporations that they are distracted from their own 
economy's actual basis in nature. They also have not paid enough attention 
to the difference between their always threatened local economies and the 
apparently thriving corporate economy that is exploiting them. 

On the other hand, the mostly urban conservationists, who mostly are 
ignorant of the economic adversities of, say, family-scale farming or ranch- 
ing, have paid far too little attention to the connection between their eco- 
nomic life and the despoliation of nature.They have trouble seeing that the 
bad farming and forestry practices that they oppose as conservationists are 
done on their behalf, and with their consent implied in the economic prox- 
ies they have given as consumers. 

These clearly are serious problems. Both of them indicate that the 
industrial economy is not a true description of economic reality, and more- 
over that this economy has been wonderfully successful in getting its false- 
hoods believed. Too many land users and too many conservationists seem 
to have accepted the doctrine that the availability of goods is determined 
by the availability of cash, or credit, and by the market. In other words, they 
have accepted the idea always implicit in the arguments of the land-exploit- 
ing corporations: that there can be, and that there is, a safe disconnection 
between economy and ecology, between human domesticity and the wild 
world. Industrializing farmers have too readily assumed that the nature of 
their land could safely be subordinated to the capability of their technolo- 



CONSERVATIONIST AND AGRARIAN 83 



gy, and that conservation could safely be left to conservationists. 
Conservationists have too readily assumed that the integrity of the natural 
world could be preserved mainly by preserving tracts of wilderness, and 
that the nature and nurture of the economic landscapes could safely be left 
to agribusiness, the timber industry, debt-ridden farmers and ranchers, and 
migrant laborers. 

To me, it appears that these two sides are as divided as they are because 
each is clinging to its own version of a common economic error. How can 
this be corrected? I don't think it can be, so long as each of the two sides 
remains closed up in its own conversation. I think the two sides need to 
enter into one conversation. They have got to talk to one another. Conser- 
vationists have got to know and deal competently with the methods and 
economics of land use. Land users have got to recognize the urgency, even 
the economic urgency, of the requirements of conservation. 

Failing this, these two sides will simply concede an easy victory to their 
common enemy, the third side, the corporate totalitarianism which is now 
rapidly consolidating as "the global economy" and which will utterly domi- 
nate both the natural world and its human communities. 



Sanitation and the Small Farm 



(1971) 



IN THE TIME when my memories begin— the late 1930s— people in the 
country did not go around empty-handed as much as they do now. As I 
remember them from that time, farm people on the way somewhere char- 
acteristically had buckets or kettles or baskets in their hands, sometimes 
sacks on their shoulders. 

Those were hard times— not unusual in our agricultural history— and so 
a lot of the fetching and carrying had to do with foraging, searching the 
fields and woods for nature's free provisions: greens in the spring-time, 
fruits and berries in the summer, nuts in the fall. There was fishing in warm 
weather and hunting in cold weather; people did these things for food and 
for pleasure, not for "sport." The economies of many house holds were small 
and thorough, and people took these seasonal opportunities seriously. 

For the same reason, they practiced household husbandry. They 
raised gardens, fattened meat hogs, milked cows, kept flocks of chickens 
and other poultry. These enterprises were marginal to the farm, but cen- 
tral to the household. In a sense, they comprised the direct bond between 
farm and household.These enterprises produced surpluses which, in those 
days, were marketable. And so when one saw farm people in town they 
would be laden with buckets of cream or baskets of eggs. Or maybe you 
would see a woman going into the grocery store, carrying two or three old 
hens with their legs tied together. Sometimes this surplus paid for what 
the family had to buy at the store. Sometimes after they "bought" their gro- 
ceries in this way, they had money to take home. These households were 



85 



86 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



places of production, at least some of the time operating at a net econom- 
ic gain. The idea of "consumption" was alien to them. I am not talking 
about practices of exceptional families, but about what was ordinarily 
done on virtually all farms. 

That economy was in the truest sense democratic. Everybody could 
participate in it-even little children. An important source of instruction 
and pleasure to a child growing up on a farm was participation in the fam- 
ily economy. Children learned about the adult world by participating in it 
in a small way, by doing a little work and making a little money— a much 
more effective, because pleasurable, and a much cheaper method than the 
present one of requiring the adult world to be learned in the abstract in 
school. One's elders in those days were always admonishing one to save 
nickels and dimes, and there was tangible purpose in their advice: With 
enough nickels and dimes, one could buy a cow or a sow; with the income 
from a cow or a sow, one could begin to save to buy a farm. This scheme 
was plausible enough, evidently, for it seemed that all grown-ups had med- 
itated on it. Now, according to the savants of agriculture— and most 
grownups now believe them— one does not start in farming with a sow or a 
cow; one must start with a quarter of a million dollars. What are the polit- 
ical implications of that economy? 

I have so far mentioned only the most common small items of trade, 
but it was also possible to sell prepared foods: pies, bread, butter, beaten 
biscuits, cured hams, etc. And among the most attractive enterprises of that 
time were the small dairies that were added without much expense or trou- 
ble to the small, diversified farms. There would usually be a milking room 
or stall partitioned off in a barn, with homemade wooden stanchions to 
accommodate perhaps three to half a dozen cows. The cows were milked by 
hand. The milk was cooled in cans in a tub of well water. For a minimal 
expenditure and an hour or so of effort night and morning, the farm 
gained a steady, dependable income. All this conformed to the ideal of my 
grandfather's generation of farmers, which was to "sell something every 
week"— a maxim of diversity, stability, and small scale. 

Both the foraging in fields and woods and the small husbandries of 
household and barn have now been almost entirely replaced by the "con- 



SANITATION AND THE SMALL FARM 



87 



sumer economy," which assumes that it is better to buy whatever one needs 
than to find it or make it or grow it. Advertisements and other forms of 
propaganda suggest that people should congratulate themselves on the 
quantity and variety of their purchases. Shopping, in spite of traffic and 
crowds, is held to be "easy" and "convenient." Spending money gives one 
status. And physical exertion for any useful purpose is looked down upon; 
it is permissible to work hard for "sport" or "recreation," but to make any 
practical use of the body is considered beneath dignity. 

Aside from the fashions of leisure and affluence-so valuable to corpo- 
rations, so destructive of values-the greatest destroyer of the small 
economies of the small farms has been the doctrine of sanitation. I have no 
argument against cleanliness and healthfulness; I am for them as much as 
anyone. I do, however, question the validity and the honesty of the sanita- 
tion laws that have come to rule over farm production in the last thirty or 
forty years. Why have new sanitation laws always required more, and more 
expensive, equipment? Why have they always worked against the survival of 
the small producer? Is it impossible to be inexpensively healthful and clean? 

I am not a scientist or a sanitation expert, and cannot give conclusive 
answers to those questions; I can only say what I have observed and what I 
think. In a remarkably short time I have seen the demise of all the small 
dairy operations in my part of the country, the shutting down of all local 
creameries and of all the small local dealers in milk and milk products. I 
have seen the grocers forced to quit dealing in eggs produced by local farm- 
ers, and have seen the closing of all markets for small quantities of poultry. 

Recently, in continuation of the "trend," the local slaughterhouses in 
Kentucky were required to make expensive alterations or go out of busi- 
ness. Most of them went out of business. These were not offering meat for 
sale in the wholesale or retail trade. They did custom work mainly for local 
farmers who brought their animals in for slaughter and took the meat 
home or to a locker plant for processing.They were essential to the effort 
of many people to live self-sufficiently from their own produce— and these 
people had raised no objections to the way their meat was being handled. 
The few establishments that managed to survive this "improvement" found 
it necessary, of course, to charge higher prices for their work. Who benefit- 



88 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



ed from this? Not the customers, who were put to considerable expense and 
inconvenience, if they were not forced to quit producing their own meat 
altogether. Not, certainly, the slaughterhouses or the local economies. Not, 
so far as I can see, the public's health. The only conceivable beneficiaries 
were the meatpacking corporations, and for this questionable gain local life 
was weakened at its economic roots. 

This sort of thing is always justified as "consumer protection." But we 
need to ask a few questions about that. How are consumers protected by a 
system that puts more and more miles, middlemen, agencies, and inspec- 
tors between them and the producers? How, over all these obstacles, can 
consumers make producers aware of their tastes and needs? How are con- 
sumers protected by a system that apparently cannot "improve" except by 
eliminating the small producer, increasing the cost of production, and 
increasing the retail price of the product? 

Does the concentration of production in the hands of fewer and fewer 
big operators really serve the ends of cleanliness and health? Or does it 
make easier and more lucrative the possibility of collusion between irre- 
sponsible producers and corrupt inspectors? 

In so strenuously and expensively protecting food from contamina- 
tion by germs, how much have we increased the possibility of its contam- 
ination by antibiotics, preservatives, and various industrial poisons? The 
notorious PBB disaster in Michigan could probably not have happened in 
a decentralized system of small local suppliers and producers. 

And, finally, what do we do to our people, our communities, our econ- 
omy, and our political system when we allow our necessities to be produced 
by a centralized system of large operators, dependent on expensive technol- 
ogy, and regulated by expensive bureaucracy? The modern food industry is 
said to be a "miracle of technology." But it is well to remember that this 
technology, in addition to so-called miracles, produces economic and polit- 
ical consequences that are not favorable to democracy. 

The connections among farming, technology, economics, and politics 
are important for many reasons, one of the most obvious being their influ- 
ence on food production. Probably the worst fault of our present system is 
that it simply eliminates from production the land that is not suitable for, 



SANITATION AND THE SMALL FARM 



89 



as well as the people who cannot afford, large-scale technology. And it 
ignores the potential productivity of these "marginal" acres and people. 

It is possible to raise these issues because our leaders have been 
telling us for years that our agriculture needs to become more and more 
productive. If they mean what they say, they will have to revise produc- 
tion standards and open the necessary markets to provide a livelihood for 
small farmers. Only small farmers can keep the so-called marginal land in 
production, for only they can give the intensive care necessary to keep it 
productive. 



Renewing Husbandry 



(2004) 



I REMEMBER WELL A summer morning in about 1950 when my father sent 
a hired man with a McCormick High Gear No. 9 mowing machine and 
a team of mules to the field I was mowing with our nearly new Farmall A. 
That memory is a landmark in my mind and my history. I had been born 
into the way of farming represented by the mule team, and I loved it. I 
knew irresistibly that the mules were good ones. They were stepping along 
beautifully at a rate of speed in fact only a little slower than mine. But now 
I saw them suddenly from the vantage point of the tractor, and I remem- 
ber how fiercely I resented their slowness. I saw them as "in my way." For 
those who have had no similar experience, I was feeling exactly the outrage 
and the low-grade superiority of a hotrodder caught behind an aged 
dawdler in urban traffic. It is undoubtedly significant that in the summer 
of 1950 I passed my sixteenth birthday and became eligible to solve all my 
problems by driving an automobile. 

This is not an exceptional or a remarkably dramatic bit of history. I 
recite it here to confirm that the industrialization of agriculture is a part of 
my familiar experience. I don't have the privilege of looking at it as an out- 
sider. It is not incomprehensible to me. The burden of this essay, on the 
contrary, is that the industrialization of agriculture is a grand oversimplifi- 
cation, too readily comprehensible, to me and to everybody else. 

We were mowing that morning, the teamster with his mules and I with 
the tractor, in the field behind the barn on my father's home place, where 
he and before him his father had been born, and where his father had died 



91 



92 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



in February of 1946. The old way of farming was intact in my grandfather's 
mind until the day he died at eighty-two. He had worked mules all his life, 
understood them thoroughly, and loved the good ones passionately. He 
knew tractors only from a distance, he had seen only a few of them, and he 
rejected them out of hand because he thought, correctly, that they compact- 
ed the soil. 

Even so, four years after his death his grandson's sudden resentment of 
the "slow" mule team foretold what history would bear out: The tractor 
would stay and the mules would go.Year after year, agriculture would be 
adapted more and more to the technology and the processes of industry 
and to the rule of industrial economics.This transformation occurred with 
astonishing speed because, by the measures it set for itself, it was wonder- 
fully successful. It "saved labor," it conferred the prestige of modernity, and 
it was highly productive. 

THOUGH I NEVER entirely departed from farming or at least from thoughts 
of farming, and my affection for my homeland remained strong, during the 
fourteen years after 1950 I was much away from home and was not giving 
to farming the close and continuous attention I have given to it in the forty 
years since. 

In 1964 my family and I returned to Kentucky, and in a year were set- 
tled on a hillside farm in my native community, where we have continued 
to live. Perhaps because I was a returned traveler intending to stay, I now 
saw the place more clearly than before. I saw it critically, too, for it was evi- 
dent at once that the human life of the place, the life of the farms and the 
farming community, was in decline. The old self-sufficient way of farming 
was passing away. The economic prosperity that had visited the farmers 
briefly during World War II and for a few years afterward had ended.The 
little towns that once had been social and economic centers, thronged with 
country people on Saturdays and Saturday nights, were losing out to the 
bigger towns and the cities. The rural neighborhoods, once held together 
by common memories, common work, and the sharing of help, had begun 
to dissolve. There were no longer local markets for chickens or eggs or 
cream. The spring lamb industry, once a staple of the region, was gone.The 
tractors and other mechanical devices certainly were saving the labor of the 



RENEWING HUSBANDRY 93 



farmers and farm hands who had moved away, but those who had stayed 
were working harder and longer than ever. 

Because I remembered with affection and respect my grandparents and 
other country people of their generation, and because I had admirable 
friends and neighbors with whom I was again farming, I began to ask what 
was happening, and why. I began to ask what would be the effects on the 
land, on the community, on the natural world, and on the art of farming. 
And these questions have occupied me steadily ever since. 

The effects of this process of industrialization have become so appar- 
ent, so numerous, so favorable to the agribusiness corporations, and so 
unfavorable to everything else that by now the questions troubling me and 
a few others in the 1960s and 1970s are being asked everywhere. 

There are no doubt many ways of accounting for this change, but for 
convenience and brevity I am going to attribute it to the emergence of con- 
text as an issue. It has become increasingly clear that the way we farm 
affects the local community, and that the economy of the local communi- 
ty affects the way we farm; that the way we farm affects the health and 
integrity of the local ecosystem, and that the farm is intricately dependent, 
even economically, upon the health of the local ecosystem. We can no 
longer pretend that agriculture is a sort of economic machine with inter- 
changeable parts, the same everywhere, determined by "market forces" and 
independent of everything else. We are not farming in a specialist capsule 
or a professionalist department; we are farming in the world, in a webwork 
of dependences and influences more intricate than we will ever under- 
stand. It has become clear, in short, that we have been running our funda- 
mental economic enterprise by the wrong rules. We were wrong to assume 
that agriculture could be adequately defined by reductionist science and 
determinist economics. 

If you can keep the context narrow enough (and the accounting pe- 
riod short enough), then the industrial criteria of labor saving and high 
productivity seem to work well. But the old rules of ecological coherence 
and of community life have remained in effect.The costs of ignoring them 
have accumulated, until now the boundaries of our reductive and mechan- 
ical explanations have collapsed. Their collapse reveals, plainly for all to 



94 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



see, the ecological and social damages that they were meant to conceal. It 
will seem paradoxical to some that the national and global corporate 
economies have narrowed the context for thinking about agriculture, but it 
is merely the truth.Those large economies, in their understanding and in 
their accounting, have excluded any concern for the land and the people. 
Now, in the midst of much unnecessary human and ecological damage, we 
are facing the necessity of a new start in agriculture. 

AND so IT is not possible to look back at the tableau of team and tractor on 
that morning in 1950 and see it as I saw it then. That is not because I have 
changed, though obviously I have; it is because, in the fifty-four years since 
then, history and the law of consequence have widened the context of the 
scene as circles widen on water around a thrown stone. 

My impatience at the slowness of the mules, I think, was a fairly repre- 
sentative emotion. I thought I was witnessing a contest of machine against 
organism, which the machine was bound to win. I did not see that the team 
arrived at the field that morning from the history of farming and from the 
farm itself, whereas the tractor arrived from almost an opposite history, and 
by means of a process reaching a long way beyond that farm or any farm. It 
took me a long time to understand that the team belonged to the farm and 
was directly supportable by it, whereas the tractor belonged to an economy 
that would remain alien to agriculture, functioning entirely by means of 
distant supplies and long supply lines.The tractor's arrival had signaled, 
among other things, agriculture's shift from an almost exclusive depend- 
ence on free solar energy to a total dependence on costly fossil fuel. But in 
1950, like most people at that time, I was years away from the first inkling 
of the limits of the supply of cheap fuel. 

We had entered an era of limitlessness, or the illusion thereof, and this 
in itself is a sort of wonder. My grandfather lived a life of limits, both suf- 
fered and strictly observed, in a world of limits. I learned much of that 
world from him and others, and then I changed; I entered the world of 
labor-saving machines and of limitless cheap fossil fuel. It would take me 
years of reading, thought, and experience to learn again that in this world 
limits are not only inescapable but indispensable. 

My purpose here is not to disturb the question of the use of draft ani- 



RENEWING HUSBANDRY 95 



mals in agriculture— though I doubt that it will sleep indefinitely. I want 
instead to talk about the tractor as an influence. The means we use to do 
our work almost certainly affect the way we look at the world. If the frag- 
ment of autobiography I began with means anything, it means that my 
transformation from a boy who had so far grown up driving a team to a boy 
driving a tractor was a sight-changing experience. 

Brought up as a teamster but now driving a tractor, a boy almost sud- 
denly, almost perforce, sees the farm in a different way: as ground to be got 
over by a means entirely different, at an entirely different cost. The team, 
like the boy, would grow weary, but that weariness has all at once been sub- 
tracted, and the boy is now divided from the ground by the absence of a 
living connection that enforced sympathy as a practical good. The tractor 
can work at maximum speed hour after hour without tiring. There is no 
longer a reason to remember the shady spots where it was good to stop and 
rest.Tirelessness and speed enforce a second, more perilous change in the 
way the boy sees the farm: Seeing it as ground to be got over as fast as pos- 
sible and, ideally, without stopping, he has taken on the psychology of a 
traveler by interstate highway or by air. The focus of his attention has shift- 
ed from the place to the technology. 

I now suspect that if we work with machines the world will seem to us 
to be a machine, but if we work with living creatures the world will appear 
to us as a living creature. Be that as it may, mechanical farming certainly 
makes it easy to think mechanically about the land and its creatures. It 
makes it easy to think mechanically even about oneself, and the tirelessness 
of tractors brought a new depth of weariness into human experience, at a 
cost to health and family life that has not been fully accounted. 

Once one's farm and one's thoughts have been sufficiently mecha- 
nized, industrial agriculture's focus on production, as opposed to mainte- 
nance or stewardship, becomes merely logical. And here the trouble com- 
pletes itself. The almost exclusive emphasis on production permits the way 
of working to be determined, not by the nature and character of the farm 
in its ecosystem and in its human community, but rather by the national 
or the global economy and the available or affordable technology. The farm 
and all concerns not immediately associated with production have in effect 



96 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



disappeared from sight. The farmer too in effect has vanished. He is no 
longer working as an independent and loyal agent of his place, his family, 
and his community, but instead as the agent of an economy that is funda- 
mentally adverse to him and to all that he ought to stand for. 

After mechanization it is certainly possible for a farmer to maintain a 
proper creaturely and stewardly awareness of the lives in her keeping. If you 
look, you can still find farmers who are farming well on mechanized farms. 
After mechanization, however, to maintain this kind of awareness requires 
a distinct effort of will. And if we ask what are the cultural resources that 
can inform and sustain such an effort of will, I believe that we will find 
them gathered under the heading of husbandry, and here my essay arrives 
finally at its subject. 

The WORD husbandry is the name of a connection. In its original sense, it is 
the name of the work of a domestic man, a man who has accepted a 
bondage to the household. We have no cause here, I think, to raise the 
issue of "sexual roles." We need only to say that our earthly life requires 
both husbandry and housewifery, and that nobody, certainly no house- 
hold, is excused from a proper attendance to both. 

Husbandry pertains first to the household; it connects the farm to the 
household. It is an art wedded to the art of housewifery. To husband is to 
use with care, to keep, to save, to make last, to conserve. Old usage tells us 
that there is a husbandry also of the land, of the soil, of the domestic plants 
and animals— obviously because of the importance of these things to the 
household. And there have been times, one of which is now, when some 
people have tried to practice a proper human husbandry of the nondomes- 
tic creatures in recognition of the dependence of our households and 
domestic life upon the wild world. Husbandry is the name of all the prac- 
tices that sustain life by connecting us conservingly to our places and our 
world; it is the art of keeping tied all the strands in the living network that 
sustains us. 

And so it appears that most and perhaps all of industrial agriculture's 
manifest failures are the result of an attempt to make the land produce 
without husbandry. The attempt to remake agriculture as a science and 
an industry has excluded from it the age-old husbandry that was central 



RENEWING HUSBANDRY 97 



and essential to it, and that denoted always the fundamental domestic 
connections and demanded a restorative care in the use of the land and 
its creatures. 

This effort had its initial and probably its most radical success in sepa- 
rating farming from the economy of subsistence. Through World War II, 
farm life in my region (and, I think, nearly everywhere) rested solidly upon 
the garden, dairy, poultry flock, and meat animals that fed the farm's fam- 
ily. Especially in hard times these farm families, and their farms too, sur- 
vived by means of their subsistence economy. This was the husbandry and 
the housewifery by which the farm lived. The industrial program, on the 
contrary, suggested that it was "uneconomic" for a farm family to produce 
its own food; the effort and the land would be better applied to commer- 
cial production. The result is utterly strange in human experience: farm 
families who buy everything they eat at the store. 

An intention to replace husbandry with science was made explicit in the 
renaming of disciplines in the colleges of agriculture. "Soil husbandry" 
became "soil science," and "animal husbandry" became "animal science." 
This change is worth lingering over because of what it tells us about our 
susceptibility to poppycock. When any discipline is made or is called a sci- 
ence, it is thought by some to be much increased in preciseness, complexi- 
ty, and prestige.When "husbandry" becomes "science," the lowly has been 
exalted and the rustic has become urbane. Purporting to increase the 
sophistication of the humble art of farming, this change in fact brutally 
oversimplifies it. 

"Soil science," as practiced by soil scientists, and even more as it has 
been handed down to farmers, has tended to treat the soil as a lifeless ma- 
trix in which "soil chemistry" takes place and "nutrients" are "made avail- 
able." And this, in turn, has made farming increasingly shallow— literally 
so— in its understanding of the soil. The modern farm is understood as a 
surface on which various mechanical operations are performed, and to 
which various chemicals are applied. The under-surface reality of organisms 
and roots is mostly ignored. 

"Soil husbandry" is a different kind of study, involving a different kind 
of mind. Soil husbandry leads, in the words of Sir Albert Howard, to 



98 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



understanding "health in soil, plant, animal, and man as one great sub- 
ject."We apply the word "health" only to living creatures, and to soil hus- 
bandry a healthy soil is a wilderness, mostly unstudied and unknown, but 
teemingly alive. The soil is at once a living community of creatures and 
their habitat.The farm's husband, its family, its crops and animals, all are 
members of the soil community; all belong to the character and identity of 
the place. To rate the farm family merely as "labor" and its domestic plants 
and animals merely as "production" is thus an oversimplification, both rad- 
ical and destructive. 

"Science" is too simple a word to name the complex of relationships 
and connections that compose a healthy farm-a farm that is a full member- 
ship of the soil community. If we propose not the reductive science we gen- 
erally have, but a science of complexity, that too will be inadequate, for any 
complexity that science can comprehend is going to be necessarily a human 
construct, and therefore too simple. 

The husbandry of mere humans of course cannot be complex enough 
either. But husbandry always has understood that what is husbanded is ul- 
timately a mystery. A farmer, as one of his farmer correspondents once 
wrote to Liberty Hyde Bailey, is "a dispenser of the 'Mysteries of God.'" The 
mothering instinct of animals, for example, is a mystery that husbandry 
must use and trust mostly without understanding. The husband, unlike the 
"manager" or the would-be objective scientist, belongs inherently to the 
complexity and the mystery that is to be husbanded, and so the husband- 
ing mind is both careful and humble. Husbandry originates precautionary 
sayings like "Don't put all your eggs into one basket" and "Don't count your 
chickens before they hatch." It does not boast of technological feats that 
will "feed the world." 

Husbandry, which is not replaceable by science, nevertheless uses sci- 
ence, and corrects it too. It is the more comprehensive discipline. To 
reduce husbandry to science, in practice, is to transform agricultural 
"wastes" into pollutants, and to subtract perennials and grazing animals 
from the rotation of crops.Without husbandry, the agriculture of science 
and industry has served too well the purpose of the industrial economy in 
reducing the number of landowners and the self-employed. It has trans- 



RENEWING HUSBANDRY 99 



formed the United States from a country of many owners to a country of 
many employees. 

WITHOUT HUSBANDRY, "soil science" too easily ignores the community of 
creatures that live in and from, that make and are made by, the soil. 
Similarly, "animal science" without husbandry forgets, almost as a require- 
ment, the sympathy by which we recognize ourselves as fellow creatures of 
the animals. It forgets that animals are so called because we once believed 
them to be endowed with souls. Animal science has led us away from that 
belief or any such belief in the sanctity of animals. It has led us instead to 
the animal factory, which, like the concentration camp, is a vision of Hell. 
Animal husbandry, on the contrary, comes from and again leads to the 
psalmist's vision of good grass, good water, and the husbandry of God. 

(It is only a little off my subject to notice also that the high and essen- 
tial art of housewifery, later known as "home economics," has now become 
"family and consumer science." This presumably elevates the intellectual 
standing of the faculty by removing family life and consumption from the 
context— and the economy-of a home or household.) 

Agriculture must mediate between nature and the human commu- 
nity, with ties and obligations in both directions. To farm well requires an 
elaborate courtesy toward all creatures, animate and inanimate. It is sympa- 
thy that most appropriately enlarges the context of human work. Contexts 
become wrong by being too small— too small, that is, to contain the scien- 
tist or the farmer or the farm family or the local ecosystem or the local com- 
munity-and this is crucial. "Out of context," as Wes Jackson has said, "the 
best minds do the worst damage." 

Looking for a way to give an exact sense of this necessary sympathy, the 
feeling of husbandry at work, I found it in a book entitled Feed My Sheep by 
Terry Cummins. Mr. Cummins is a man of about my age, who grew up 
farming with his grandfather in Pendleton County, Kentucky, in the 1940s 
and early '50s. In the following sentences he is remembering himself at the 
age of thirteen, in about 1947: 

When you see that you're making the other things feel good, it gives you 
a good feeling, too. 



100 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



The feeling inside sort of just happens, and you can't say this did it or 
that did it. It's the many little things. It doesn't seem that taking 
sweat-soaked harnesses off tired, hot horses would he something that 
would make you notice. Opening a barn door for the sheep standing 
out in a cold rain, or throwing a few grains of corn to the chickens are 
small things, but these little things begin to add up in you, and you 
can be- gin to understand that you're important.You may not be real 
important like people who do great things that you read about in the 
newspaper, but you begin to feel that you're important to all the life 
around you. 'Nobody else knows or cares too much about what you do, 
but if you get a good feeling inside about what you do, then it doesn't 
matter if nobody else knows. I do think about myself a lot when I'm 
alone way back on the place bringing in the cows or sitting on a mow- 
ing machine all day. But when I start thinking about how our animals 
and crops and fields and woods and gardens sort of all fit together, 
then 1 get that good feeling inside and don't worry much about what 
will happen to me. 

This passage goes to the heart of what I am trying to say, because it goes to 
the heart of farming as I have known it. Mr. Cummins's sentences describe 
an experience regrettably and perhaps dangerously missing now from the 
childhood of most children. They also describe the communion between 
the farmer as husband and the well-husbanded farm. This communion is a 
cultural force that can exist only by becoming personal. 
To see it so described is to understand at once how necessary and how 
threatened it now is. 

I HAVE TRIED to say what husbandry is, how it works, and why it is neces- 
sary. Now I want to speak of two paramount accomplishments of hus- 
bandry to which I think we will have to pay more deliberate attention, in 
our present circumstances, than we ever have before. These are local adap- 
tation and local coherence of form. It is strange that a science of agricul- 
ture founded on evolutionary biology, with its practical emphasis on sur- 
vival, would exempt the human species from these concerns. 

True husbandry, as its first strategy of survival, has always striven to fit 



RENEWING HUSBANDRY 101 



the farming to the farm and to the field, to the needs and abilities of the 
farm's family, and to the local economy. Every wild creature is the product 
of such an adaptive process. The same process once was a dominant influ- 
ence on agriculture, for the cost of ignoring it was hunger. One striking and 
well-known example of local adaptation in agriculture is the number and 
diversity of British sheep breeds, most of which are named for the localities 
in which they were developed. But local adaptation must be even more 
refined than this example suggests, for it involves consideration of the indi- 
viduality of every farm and every field. 

Our recent focus upon productivity, genetic and technological unifor- 
mity, and global trade— all supported by supposedly limitless supplies of 
fuel, water, and soil-has obscured the necessity for local adaptation. But 
our circumstances are changing rapidly now, and this requirement will be 
forced upon us again by terrorism and other kinds of political violence, by 
chemical pollution, by increasing energy costs, by depleted soils, aquifers, 
and streams, and by the spread of exotic weeds, pests, and diseases. We are 
going to have to return to the old questions about local nature, local carry- 
ing capacities, and local needs. And we are going to have to resume the 
breeding of plants and animals to fit the region and the farm. 

The same obsessions and extravagances that have caused us to ignore 
the issue of local adaptation have at the same time caused us to ignore the 
issue of form. These two issues are so closely related that it is difficult to 
talk about one without talking about the other. During the half century 
and more of our neglect of local adaptation, we have subjected our farms 
to a radical oversimplification of form. The diversified and reasonably 
self-sufficient farms of my region and of many other regions have been 
conglomerated into larger farms with larger fields, increasingly special- 
ized, and subjected increasingly to the strict, unnatural linearity of the 
production line. 

But the first requirement of a form is that it must be comprehensive; 
it must not leave out something that essentially belongs within it. The farm 
that Terry Cummins remembers was remarkably comprehensive, and it was 
not any one of its several enterprises alone that made him feel good, but 
rather "how our animals and crops and fields and woods and gardens sort 



102 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



of all fit together." 

The form of the farm must answer to the farmer's feeling for the place, 
its creatures, and its work. It is a never-ending effort of fitting together 
many diverse things. It must incorporate the life cycle and the fertility 
cycles of animals. It must bring crops and livestock into balance and mutu- 
al support. It must be a pattern on the ground and in the mind. It must be 
at once ecological, agricultural, economic, fa milial, and neighborly. It 
must be inclusive enough, complex enough, coherent, intelligible, and 
durable. It must have within its limits the completeness of an organism or 
an ecosystem, or of any other good work of art. 

The making of a form begins in the recognition and acceptance of lim- 
its. The farm is limited by its topography, its climate, its ecosystem, its 
human neighborhood and local economy, and of course by the larger 
economies, and by the preferences and abilities of the farmer. The true hus- 
bandman shapes the farm within an assured sense of what it cannot be and 
what it should not be. And thus the problem of form returns us to that of 
local adaptation. 

The TASK BEFORE us, now as always before, is to renew and husband the 
means, both natural and human, of agriculture. But to talk now about 
renewing husbandry is to talk about unsimplifying what is in reality an 
extremely complex subject. This will require us to accept again, and more 
competently than before, the health of the ecosystem, the farm, and the 
human community as the ultimate standard of agricultural performance. 

Unsimplification is difficult, I imagine, in any circumstances; our pres- 
ent circumstances will make it especially so. Soon the majority of the 
world's people will be living in cities. We are now obliged to think of so 
many people demanding the means of life from the land, to which they will 
no longer have a practical connection, and of which they will have little 
knowledge. We are obliged also to think of the consequences of any 
attempt to meet this demand by large-scale, expensive, petroleum-depend- 
ent technological schemes that will ignore local conditions and local needs. 
The problem of renewing husbandry, and the need to promote a general 
awareness of everybody's agricultural responsibilities, thus become urgent. 



RENEWING HUSBANDRY 103 



How are we to do this? How can we restore a competent husbandry to 
the minds of the world's producers and consumers? 

For a start of course we must recognize that this effort is already in 
progress on many farms and in many urban consumer groups scattered 
across our country and the world. But we must recognize too that this 
effort needs an authorizing focus and force that would grant it a new legit- 
imacy, intellectual rigor, scientific respectability, and responsible teaching. 
There are many reasons to hope that this might be supplied by our colleges 
of agriculture, and there are some reasons to think that this hope is not 
fantastical. 

With that hope in mind, I want to return to the precaution that I men- 
tioned earlier. The effort of husbandry is partly scientific, but it is entirely 
cultural, and a cultural initiative can exist only by becoming personal. It 
will become increasingly clear, I believe, that agricultural scientists, and the 
rest of us as well, are going to have to be less specialized, or less isolated by 
our specialization. Agricultural scientists will need to work as indwelling 
members of agricultural communities or of consumer communities. Their 
scientific work will need to accept the limits and the influence of that mem- 
bership. It is not irrational to propose that a significant number of these 
scientists should be farmers, and so subject their scientific work, and that 
of their colleagues, to the influence of a farmer's practical circumstances. 
Along with the rest of us, they will need to accept all the imperatives of hus- 
bandry as the context of their work. We cannot keep things from falling 
apart in our society if they do not cohere in our minds and in our lives. 



PART II 
FARMERS 



Seven Amish Farms 



(1981) 



IN TYPICAL MIDWESTERN farming country the distances between inhabit- 
ed houses are stretching out as bigger farmers buy out their smaller 
neighbors in order to "stay in." The signs of this "movement" and its conse- 
quent specialization are everywhere: good houses standing empty, going to 
ruin; good stock barns going to ruin; pasture fences fallen down or gone; 
machines too large for available doorways left in the weather; windbreaks 
and woodlots gone down before the bulldozers; small schoolhouses and 
churches deserted or filled with grain. 

In the latter part of March this country shows little life. Field after field 
lies under the dead stalks of last year's corn and soybeans, or lies broken for 
the next crop; one may drive many miles between fields that are either sod- 
ded or planted in winter grain. If the weather is wet, the country will seem 
virtually deserted. If the ground is dry enough to support their wheels, 
there will be tractors at work, huge machines with glassed cabs, rolling into 
the distances of fields larger than whole farms used to be, as solitary as 
seaborne ships. 

The difference between such country and the Amish farmlands in 
northeast Indiana seems almost as great as that between a desert and an 
oasis. And it is the same difference. In the Amish country there is a great 
deal more life: more natural life, more agricultural life, more human life. 
Because the farms are small-most of them containing well under a hun- 
dred acres— the Amish neighborhoods are more thickly populated than 
most rural areas, and you see more people at work. And because the Amish 



107 



108 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



are diversified farmers, their plowed croplands are interspersed with pas- 
tures and hayfields and often with woodlots. It is a varied, interesting, 
healthy-looking farm country, pleasant to drive through.When we were 
there, on the twentieth and twenty-first of last March, the spring plowing 
had just started, and so you could still see everywhere the annual covering 
of stable manure on the fields, and the teams of Belgians or Percherons still 
coming out from the barns with loaded spreaders. 

Our host, those days, was William J. Yoder, a widely respected breeder 
of Belgian horses, an able farmer and carpenter, and a most generous and 
enjoyable companion. He is a vigorous man, strenuously involved in the 
work of his farm and in the life of his family and community. From the 
look of him and the look of his place, you know that he has not just done 
a lot of work in his time, but has done it well, learned from it, mastered the 
necessary disciplines. He speaks with heavy stress on certain words— the 
emphasis of conviction, but also of pleasure, for he enjoys the talk that goes 
on among people interested in horses and in farming. But unlike many 
people who enjoy talking, he speaks with care. Bill was born in this com- 
munity, has lived there all his life, and he has grandchildren who will prob- 
ably live there all their lives. He belongs there, then, root and branch, and 
he knows the history and the quality of many of the farms. On the two 
days, we visited farms belonging to Bill himself, four of his sons, and two 
of his sons-in-law. 

The Amish farms tend to divide up between established ones, which 
are prosperous-looking and well maintained, and run-down, abused, or 
neglected ones, on which young farmers are getting started. Young Amish 
farmers are still getting started, in spite of inflation, speculators' prices, and 
usurious interest rates. My impression is that the proportion of young farm- 
ers buying farms is significantly greater among the Amish than among con- 
ventional farmers. 

Bill Yoder's own eighty-acre farm is among the established ones. I had 
been there in the fall of 1975 and had not forgotten its aspect of cleanness 
and good order, its well-kept white buildings, neat lawns, and garden plots. 
Bill has owned the place for twenty-six years. Before he bought it, it had 
been rented and row cropped, with the usual result: It was nearly played 



SEVEN AMISH FARMS 109 



out. "The buildings," he says, "were nothing," and there were no fences. The 
first year, the place produced five loads (maybe five tons) of hay, "and that 
was mostly sorrel." The only healthy plants on it were the spurts of grass 
and clover that grew out of the previous year's manure piles. The corn crop 
that first year "might have been thirty bushels an acre," all nubbins. The 
sandy soil blew in every strong wind, and when he plowed the fields his 
horses' feet sank into "quicksand potholes" that the share uncovered. 

The remedy has been a set of farming practices traditional among the 
Amish since the seventeenth century: diversification, rotation of crops, use 
of manure, seeding of legumes. These practices began when the Anabaptist 
sects were disfranchised in their European homelands and forced to the 
use of poor soil. We saw them still working to restore farmed-out soils in 
Indiana. One thing these practices do is build humus in the soil, and 
humus does several things: increases fertility, improves soil structure, 
improves both water-holding capacity and drainage. "No humus, you're in 
trouble," Bill says. 

After his rotations were established and the land had begun to be prop- 
erly manured, the potholes disappeared, and the soil quit blowing. "There's 
something in it now— there's some substance there." Now the farm pro- 
duces abundant crops of corn, oats, wheat, and alfalfa. Oats now yield 
90—100 bushels per acre. The corn averages 100—125 bushels per acre, and 
the ears are long, thick, and well filled. 

Bill's rotation begins and ends with alfalfa. Every fall he puts in a new 
seeding of alfalfa with his wheat; every spring he plows down an old stand 
of alfalfa, "no matter how good it is." From alfalfa he goes to corn for two 
years, planting thirty acres, twenty-five for ear corn and five for silage. After 
the second year of corn, he sows oats in the spring, wheat and alfalfa in the 
fall. In the fourth year the wheat is harvested; the alfalfa then comes on and 
remains through the fifth and sixth years. Two cuttings of alfalfa are taken 
each year. After curing in the field, the hay is hauled to the barn, chopped, 
and blown into the loft. The third cutting is pastured. 

Unlike cow manure, which is heavy and chunky, horse manure is light 
and breaks up well coming out of the spreader; it interferes less with the 
growth of small seedlings and is less likely to be picked up by a hay rake. 



110 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



On Bill's place, horse manure is used on the fall seedings of wheat and 
alfalfa, on the young alfalfa after the wheat harvest, and both years on the 
established alfalfa stands. The cow manure goes on the corn ground both 
years. He usually has about 350 eighty-bushel spreader loads of manure, 
and each year he covers the whole farm-cropland, hayland, and pasture. 

With such an abundance of manure there obviously is no dependence 
on chemical fertilizers, but Bill uses some as a "starter" on his corn and 
oats. On corn he applies 125 pounds of nitrogen in the row. On oats he 
uses 200-250 pounds of 16-16-16, 20-20-20, or 24-24-24. He routinely 
spreads two tons of lime to the acre on the ground being prepared for 
wheat. 

His out-of-pocket costs per acre of corn last year were as follows: 

Seed (planted at a rate of seven acres per bushel) - $7.00 
Fertilizer - $7.75 

Herbicide (custom applied, first year only) - $16.40 

That comes to a total of $31.15 per acre-or, if the corn makes only a hun- 
dred bushels per acre, a little over $0.31 per bushel. In the second year his 
per-acre cost is $14.75, less than $0.15 per bushel, bringing the two-year 
average to $22.95 per acre or about $0.23 per bushel. 

The herbicide is used because, extra horses being on the farm during 
the winter, Bill has to buy eighty to a hundred tons of hay, and in that way 
brings in weed seed. He had no weed problem until he started buying hay. 
Even though he uses the herbicide, he still cultivates his corn three times. 

His cost per acre of oats came to $33.00 ($12.00 for seed and $21.00 
for fertilizer)-or, at ninety bushels per acre, about $0.37 per bushel. 

Of Bill's eighty acres, sixty-two are tillable. He has ten acres of perma- 
nent pasture, and seven or eight of woodland, which produced the lumber 
for all the building he has done on the place. In addition, for $500 a year 
he rents an adjoining eighty acres of "hill and woods pasture" which pro- 
vides summer grazing for twenty heifers; and on another neighboring farm 
he rents varying amounts of cropland. 

All the field work is done with horses, and this, of course, comes vir- 



SEVEN AMISH FARMS 



111 



tually free— a by-product of the horse-breeding enterprise. Bill has an 
ancient Model D John Deere tractor that he uses for belt power. 

At the time of our visit, there were twenty-two head of horses on the 
place. But that number was unusually low, for Bill aims to keep "around 
thirty head." He has a band of excellent brood mares and three stallions, 
plus young stock of assorted ages. Since October 1 of last year, he had sold 
eighteen head of registered Belgian horses. In the winters he operates a 
"urine line," collecting "pregnant mare urine," which is sold to a pharma- 
ceutical company for the extraction of various hormones. For this pur- 
pose he boards a good many mares belonging to neighbors; that is why he 
must buy the extra hay that causes his weed problem. (Horses are so 
numerous on this farm because they are one of its money-making enter- 
prises. If horses were used only for work on this farm, four good geldings 
would be enough.) 

One bad result of the dramatic rise in draft horse prices over the last 
eight or ten years is that it has tended to focus attention on such charac- 
teristics as size and color to the neglect of less obvious qualities such as 
good feet. To me, foot quality seems a critical issue. A good horse with bad 
feet is good for nothing but decoration, and at sales and shows there are far 
too many flawed feet disguised by plastic wood and black shoe polish. And 
so I was pleased to see that every horse on Bill Yoder's place had sound, 
strong-walled, correctly shaped feet. They were good horses all around, but 
their other qualities were well-founded; they stood on good feet, and this 
speaks of the thoroughness of his judgment and also of his honesty. 

Though he is a master horseman, and the draft horse business is more 
lucrative now than ever in its history, Bill does not specialize in horses, and 
that is perhaps the clearest indication of his integrity as a farmer. Whatever 
may be the dependability of the horse economy, on this farm it rests upon 
a diversified agricultural economy that is sound. 

He was milking five Holstein cows; he had fifteen Holstein heifers that 
he had raised to sell; and he had just marketed thirty finished hogs, which 
is the number that he usually has on hand. All the animals had been well 
wintered-Bill quotes his father approvingly: "Well wintered is half sum- 
mered"— and were in excellent condition. Another saying of his father's that 



112 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



Bill likes to quote— "Keep the horses on the side of the fence the feed is 
on"— has obviously been obeyed here. The feeding is careful, the feed is 
good, and it is abundant. Though it was almost spring, there were ample 
surpluses in the hayloft and in the corn cribs. 

Other signs of the farm's good health were three sizable garden plots, 
and newly pruned grapevines and raspberry canes. The gardener of the fam- 
ily is Mrs.Yoder.Though most of the children are now gone from home, 
Bill says that she still grows as much garden stuff as she ever did. 

All SEVEN OF theYoders' sons live in the community. Floyd, the young- 
est, is still at home. Harley has a house on nearly three acres, works in town, 
and returns in the afternoons to his own shop where he works as a farrier. 
Henry, who also works in town, lives with Harley and his wife. The other 
four sons are now settled on farms that they are in the process of paying 
for. Richard has eighty acres, Orla eighty, Mel fifty-seven, and Wilbur 
eighty. Two sons-in-law also living in the community are Perry Bontrager, 
who owns ninety-five acres, and Ervin Mast, who owns sixty- five. Counting 
Bill's eighty acres, the seven families are living on 537 acres. Of the seven 
farms, only Mel's is entirely tillable, the acreages in woods or permanent 
pasture varying from five to twenty-six. 

These young men have all taken over run-down farms, on which they 
are establishing rotations and soil husbandry practices that, being tradi- 
tional, more or less resemble Bill's. It seemed generally agreed that after 
three years of this treatment the land would grow corn, as Perry Bontrager 
said, "like anywhere else." 

These are good farmers, capable of the intelligent planning, sound 
judgment, and hard work that good farming requires. Abused land heals 
and flourishes in their care. None of them expressed a wish to own more 
land; all, I believe, feel that what they have will be enough-when it is paid 
for. The big problems are high land prices and high interest rates, the latter 
apparently being the worst. 

The answer, for Bill's sons so far, has been town work. All of them, 
after leaving home, have worked for Redman Industries, a manufacturer 
of mobile homes in Topeka. They do piecework, starting at seven in the 
morning and quitting at two in the afternoon, using the rest of the day 



SEVEN AMISH FARMS 113 



for farming or other work. This, Bill thinks, is now "the only way" to get 
started farming. Even so, there is "a lot of debt" in the community— "more 
than ever." 

With a start in factory work, with family help, with government and 
bank loans, with extraordinary industry and perseverance, with highly 
developed farming skills, it is still possible for young Amish families to own 
a small farm that will eventually support them. But there is more strain in 
that effort now than there used to be, and more than there should be. 
When the burden of usurious interest becomes too great, these young men 
are finding it necessary to make temporary returns to their town jobs. 

The only one who spoke of his income was Mel, who owns fifty- seven 
acres, which, he says, will be enough. He and his family milk six Holsteins. 
He had nine mares on the urine line last winter, seven of which belonged 
to him. And he had twelve brood sows. Last year his gross income was 
$43,000. Of this, $12,000 came from hogs, $7,000 from his milk cows, the 
rest from his horses and the sale of his wheat. After his production costs, 
but before payment of interest, he netted $22,000. In order to cope with 
the interest payments, Mel was preparing to return to work in town. 

These little Amish farms thus become the measure both of "conven- 
tional" American agriculture and of the cultural meaning of the national 
industrial economy. 

To begin with, these farms give the lie directly to that false god of 
"agribusiness": the so-called economy of scale. The small farm is not an 
anachronism, is not unproductive, is not unprofitable. Among the Amish, 
it is still thriving, and is still the economic foundation of what John A. 
Hostetler (in Amish Society, third edition) rightly calls "a healthy culture." 
Though they do not produce the "record-breaking yields" so touted by the 
"agribusiness" establishment, these farms are nevertheless highly produc- 
tive. And if they are not likely to make their owners rich (never an Amish 
goal), they can certainly be said to be sufficiently profitable. The economy 
of scale has helped corporations and banks, not farmers and farm commu- 
nities. It has been an economy of dispossession and waste— plutocratic, if 
not in aim, then certainly in result. 

What these Amish farms suggest, on the contrary, is that in farming 



114 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



there is inevitably a scale that is suitable both to the productive capacity of 
the land and to the abilities of the farmer; and that agricultural problems 
are to be properly solved, not in expansion, but in management, diversity, 
balance, order, responsible maintenance, good character, and in the sensi- 
ble limitation of investment and overhead. (Bill makes a careful distinction 
between "healthy" and "unhealthy" debt, a "healthy debt" being "one you 
can hope to pay off in a reasonable way.") 

Most significant, perhaps, is that while conventional agriculture, blind- 
ly following the tendency of any industry to exhaust its sources, has made 
soil erosion a national catastrophe, these Amish farms conserve the land 
and improve it in use. 

And what is one to think of a national economy that drives such ob- 
viously able and valuable farmers to factory work? What value does such an 
economy impose upon thrift, effort, skill, good husbandry, family and com- 
munity health? 

IN SPITE OF the unrelenting destructiveness of the larger economy, the 
Amish— as Hostetler points out with acknowledged surprise and 
respect— have almost doubled in population in the last twenty years. The 
doubling of a population is, of course, no significant achievement. What is 
significant is that these agricultural communities have doubled their popu- 
lation and yet remained agricultural communities during a time when conven- 
tional farmers have failed by the millions. This alone would seem to call for 
a careful look at Amish ways of farming. That those ways have, during the 
same time, been ignored by the colleges and the agencies of agriculture 
must rank as a prime intellectual wonder. 

Amish farming has been so ignored, I think, because it involves a com- 
plicated structure that is at once biological and cultural, rather than indus- 
trial or economic. I suspect that anyone who might attempt an accounting 
of the economy of an Amish farm would soon find himself dealing with vir- 
tually unaccountable values, expenses, and benefits. He would be dealing 
with biological forces and processes not always measurable, with spiritual 
and community values not quantifiable; at certain points he would be deal- 
ing with mysteries-and he would be finding that these unaccountables and 



SEVEN AMISH FARMS 115 



inscrutables have results, among others, that are economic. Hardly an 
appropriate study for the "science" of agricultural economics. 

The economy of conventional agriculture or "agribusiness" is remark- 
able for the simplicity of its arithmetic. It involves a manipulation of 
quantities that are all entirely accountable. List your costs (land, equip- 
ment, fuel, fertilizer, pesticides, herbicides, wages), add them up, subtract 
them from your earnings, or subtract your earnings from them, and you 
have the result. 

Suppose, on the other hand, that you have an eighty-acre farm that is 
not a "food factory" but your home, your given portion of Creation which 
you are morally and spiritually obliged "to dress and to keep." Suppose 
you farm, not for wealth, but to maintain the integrity and the practical 
supports of your family and community. Suppose that, the farm being 
small enough, you farm it with family work and work exchanged with 
neighbors. Suppose you have six Belgian brood mares that you use for 
field work. Suppose that you also have milk cows and hogs, and that you 
raise a variety of grain and hay crops in rotation. What happens to your 
accounting then? 

To start with, several of the costs of conventional farming are greatly 
diminished or done away with. Equipment, fertilizer, chemicals all cost 
much less. Fuel becomes feed, but you have the mares and are feeding them 
anyway; the work ration for a brood mare is not a lot more costly than a 
maintenance ration. And the horses, like the rest of the livestock, are mak- 
ing manure. Figure that in, and figure, if you can, the value of the differ- 
ence between manure and chemical fertilizer. You can probably get an esti- 
mate of the value of the nitrogen fixed by your alfalfa, but how will you 
quantify the value to the soil of its residues and deep roots? Try to compute 
the value of humus in the soil— in improved drainage, improved drought 
resistance, improved tilth, improved health. Wages, if you pay your chil- 
dren, will still be among your costs. But compute the difference between 
paying your children and paying "labor." Work exchanged with neighbors 
can be reduced to "man-hours" and assigned a dollar value. But compute 
the difference between a neighbor and "labor." Compute the value of a fam- 
ily or a community to any one of its members.We may, as we must, grant 



116 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



that among the values of family and community there is economic 
value— but what is it? 

In the Louisville Courier-Journal of April 5, 1981, the Mobil Oil 
Corporation ran an advertisement which was yet another celebration of 
"scientific agriculture." American farming, the Mobile people are of course 
happy to say, "requires more petroleum products than almost any other 
industry. A gallon of gasoline to produce a single bushel of corn, for exam- 
ple. ..." This, they say, enables "each American farmer to feed sixty-seven 
people." And they say that this is "a-maizing." 

Well, it certainly is! And the chances are good that an agriculture total- 
ly dependent on the petroleum industry is not yet as amazing as it is going 
to be. But one thing that is already sufficiently amazing is that a bushel of 
corn produced by the burning of one gallon of gasoline has already cost 
more than six times as much as a bushel of corn grown by Bill Yoder. How 
does Bill Yoder escape what may justly be called the petroleum tax on agri- 
culture? He does so by a series of substitutions: of horses for tractors, of 
feed for fuel, of manure for fertilizer, of sound agricultural methods and 
patterns for the exploitive methods and patterns of industry. But he has 
done more than that— or, rather, he and his people and their tradition have 
done more. They have substituted themselves, their families, and their 
communities for petroleum. The Amish use little petroleum-and need lit- 
tle—because they have those other things. 

I do not think that we can make sense of Amish farming until we see 
it, until we become willing to see it, as belonging essentially to the Amish 
practice of Christianity, which instructs that one's neighbors are to be 
loved as oneself. To farmers who give priority to the maintenance of their 
community, the economy of scale (that is, the economy of large scale, of 
"growth") can make no sense, for it requires the ruination and displace- 
ment of neighbors. A farm cannot be increased except by the decrease of 
a neighborhood. What the interest of the community proposes is invari- 
ably an economy of proper scale. A whole set of agricultural proprieties 
must be observed: of farm size, of methods, of tools, of energy sources, of 
plant and animal species. Community interest also requires charity, neigh- 
borliness, the care and instruction of the young, respect for the old; thus 



SEVEN AMISH FARMS 1 1 7 



it ensures its integrity and survival. Above all, it requires good stewardship 
of the land, for the community, as the Amish have always understood, is 
no better than its land. "If treated violently or exploited selfishly," John 
Hostetler writes, the land "will yield poorly." There could be no better 
statement of the meaning of the practice and the practicality of charity. 
Except to the insane narrow-mindedness of industrial economics, selfish- 
ness does not pay. 

The Amish have steadfastly subordinated economic value to the values 
of religion and community. What is too readily overlooked by a secular, 
exploitive society is that their ways of doing this are not "empty gestures" 
and are not "backward." In the first place, these ways have kept the commu- 
nities intact through many varieties of hard times. In the second place, they 
conserve the land. In the third place, they yield economic benefits. The 
community, the religious fellowship, has many kinds of value, and among 
them is economic value. It is the result of the practice of neighborliness, 
and of the practice of stewardship. What moved me most, what I liked best, 
in those days we spent with BillYoder was the sense of the continuity of the 
community in his dealings with his children and in their dealings with 
their children. 

Bill has helped his sons financially so far as he has been able. He has 
helped them with his work. He has helped them by sharing what he 
has— lending a stallion, say, at breeding time, or lending a team. And he 
helps them by buying good pieces of equipment that come up for sale. "If 
he ever gets any money," he says of one of the boys, for whom he has 
bought an implement, "he'll pay me for it. If he don't, he'll just use it." He 
has been their teacher, and he remains their advisor. But he does not stand 
before them as a domineering patriarch or "authority figure." He seems to 
speak, rather, as a representative of family and community experience. In 
their respect for him, his sons respect their tradition. They are glad for his 
help, advice, and example, but there is nothing servile in this. It seems to 
be given and taken in a kind of familial friendship, respect going both ways. 

Everywhere we went, when school was not in session, the children were 
at the barns, helping with the work, watching, listening, learning to farm 
in the way it is best learned. Wilbur told us that his eleven-year-old son had 



118 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



cultivated twenty-three acres of corn last year with a team and a riding cul- 
tivator. That reminded Bill of the way he taught Wilbur to do the same job. 

Wilbur was little then, and he loved to sit in his father's lap and drive 
the team while Bill worked the cultivator. If Wilbur could drive, Bill 
thought, he could do the rest of it. So he got off and shortened the stirrups 
so the boy could reach them with his feet. Wilbur started the team, and 
within a few steps began plowing up the corn. 

"Whoa!" he said. 

And Bill, who was walking behind him, said, "Come up!" 
And it went that way for a little bit: 
"Whoa!" 
"Come up!" 

And then Wilbur started to cry, and Bill said: " 
Don't cry! Go ahead!" 



A Good Farmer of the Old School 



(1985) 



T THE 1982 Draft Horse Sale in Columbus, Ohio, Maury Telleen 



X V summoned me over to the group of horsemen with whom he was 
talking: "Come here," he said, "I want you to hear this." One of those horse- 
men was Lancie Clippinger, and what Maury wanted me to hear was the 
story of Lancie's corn crop of the year before. 

The story, which Lancie obligingly told again, was as interesting to me 
as Maury had expected it to be. Lancie, that year, had planted forty acres 
of corn; he had also bred forty gilts that he had raised so that their pigs 
would be ready to feed when the corn would be ripe. The gilts produced 
360 pigs, an average of nine per head. When the corn was ready for har- 
vest, Lancie divided off a strip of the field with an electric fence and turned 
in the 360 shoats. After the shoats had fed on that strip for a while, Lancie 
opened a new strip for them. He then picked the strip where they had just 
fed. In that way, he fattened his 360 shoats and also harvested all the corn 
he needed for his other stock. 

The shoats brought $40,000. Lancie's expenses had been for seed corn, 
275 pounds of fertilizer per acre, and one quart per acre of herbicide. He 
did not say what the total costs amounted to, but it was clear enough that 
his net income from the forty acres of corn had been high, in a year when 
the corn itself would have brought perhaps two dollars a bushel. 

At the end of the story, I remember, Lancie and Maury had a conver- 
sation that went about like this: 




119 



120 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



"Do you farrow your sows in a farrowing house?" 
"No." 

"Oh, you do it in huts, then?" 

"No, I have a field I turn them out in. It has plenty of shade and wa- 
ter. And I see them every day." 

Here was an intelligent man, obviously, who knew the value of doing 
his own thinking and paying attention, who understood clearly that the 
profit is in the difference between costs and earnings, and who proceeded 
directly to minimize his costs. In a time when hog farmers often spend 
many thousands of dollars on highly specialized housing and equipment, 
Lancie's "hog operation" consisted almost entirely of hogs. His principal 
outlays otherwise were for the farm itself and for fencing. But what struck 
me most, I think, was the way he had employed nature and the hogs them- 
selves to his own advantage. The bred sows needed plenty of shade, water, 
and room for exercise; Lancie provided those things, and nature did the 
rest. He also supplied his own care and attention, which came free; they did 
not have to be purchased at an inflated cost from an industrial supplier. 
And then, instead of harvesting his corn mechanically, hauling it, storing 
it, grinding it, and hauling it to his shoats, he let the shoats harvest and 
grind it for themselves. He had the use of the whole hog, whereas in a "con- 
finement operation," the hog's feet, teeth, and eyes have virtually no use 
and produce no profit. 

At the next Columbus Sale, I hunted Lancie up, and again we spent a 
long time talking. We talked about draft horses, of course, but also about 
milk cows and dairying. And that part of our conversation interested me 
about as much as the hog story had the year before. What so impressed me 
was Lancie's belief that there is a limit to the number of cows that a dairy 
farmer can manage well; he thought the maximum number to be about 
twenty-five: "If a fellow milks twenty-five cows, he'll see them all." If he milks 
more than that, Lancie said, even though he may touch them all, he will 
not see them all. As in Lancie's account of his corn crop and the 360 shoats, 
the emphasis here was on the importance of seeing, of paying attention. 
That this is important economically, he made clear in something he said to 
me later: "You can take care of twenty or twenty-five cows and do it right. 



A GOOD FARMER OF THE OLD SCHOOL 



121 



More, you're overlooking things that cost you money." It is necessary, 
Lancie thinks, to limit the scale of operation, not only in dairying, but in 
all other enterprises on the farm because proper scale permits a correct bal- 
ance between work and care. The distinction he was making, it seemed to 
me, was between work, as it has been understood traditionally on the farm, 
and processing, as it is understood in industry. 

Those two conversations stayed in my mind, proving useful many times 
in my effort to understand the troubles developing in our agricultural econ- 
omy. I knew that Lancie Clippinger was one of the best farmers of the old 
school, and I promised myself that I would visit him at his farm, which I 
was finally able to do in October 1985. 

The farm is on somewhat rolling land, surrounded by woodlots and 
brushy fencerows, so that it has a little of the feeling of a large forest clear- 
ing. There are 175 acres, of which about 135 are cropped; the rest are in 
permanent pasture and woods. Although conveniently close to the state 
road, the farm is at the end of a lane, set off to itself. It is pretty and quiet, 
a pleasant place to live and to farm, as well as to visit. Lancie and his wife, 
Verna Bell, bought the place and moved there in the fall of 1971. 

When my wife and I drove into the yard, Kathy, one of Lancie's grand- 
daughters, who had evidently been watching for us, came out of the house 
to meet us. She took us out through the barn lot to a granary where Lancie, 
his son Keith, and Sherri, another granddaughter, were sacking some 
oats. We waited, talking with Kathy, while they finished the job, and then 
we went with Lancie and Keith to look at the horses. 

Lancie keeps only geldings, buying them at sales as weanlings, raising 
and breaking them, selling them, and then replacing them with new 
colts.When we were there, he had nine head: a pair of black Percherons, a 
handsome crossbred bay with black mane and tail, and six Belgians. 
Though he prefers Percherons, he does not specialize; at the sales, his only 
aim is to buy "colts that look like they'll grow into good big horses." He 
wants them big because the big ones bring the best prices, but, like nearly 
all draft horse people who use their horses, he would rather have smaller 
ones-fifteen hundred pounds or so— if he were keeping them only to work. 

The horses he led out for us were in prime condition, and he had been 



122 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



right about them: They had, sure enough, grown into good big ones. These 
horses may be destined for pulling contests and show hitches, but while 
they are at Lancie's they put in a lot of time at farm work— they work their 
way through school, you might say. Like so many farmers of his time, 
Lancie once made the change from horses to tractors, but with him this did 
not last long. He was without horses "for a little while" in the seventies, and 
after that he began to use them again. Now he uses the horses for "just 
about everything" except cutting and baling his hay and picking his corn. 
Last spring he used his big tractor only two days. The last time he went to 
use it, it wouldn't start, and he left it sitting in the shed; it was still sitting 
there at the time of our visit. 

Part of the justification for the return to the use of horses is eco- 
nomic. When he was doing all his work with tractors, Lancie's fuel bill was 
$6,000 a year; now it is about $2,000. Since the horses themselves are a 
profit-making enterprise on this farm, the $4,000 they save on fuel is 
money in the bank. But the economic reason is not the only one: 
"Pleasure," Lancie says, "is a big part of it." At the year's end, his bank 
account will show a difference that the horses have made, but day by day 
his reason for working them is that he likes to. 

He does not need nine horses in order to do his farming. He has so 
many because he needs to keep replacements on hand for the horses he 
sells. He aims, he says, to sell "two or three or four horses every year." To 
farm his 175 acres, he needs only four good geldings, although he would 
probably like to keep five, in case he needed a spare. With four horses on 
his grain drill, he can plant fifteen or twenty acres in a day. He uses four 
horses also on an eight-foot tandem disk and a springtooth harrow, and he 
can plant twelve or fifteen acres of corn a day "and not half try." 

In plowing, he goes by the old rule of thumb that you can plow an acre 
per horse per day, provided the horses are in hard condition. "If you start 
at seven in the morning and stay there the way you ought to," he says, "you 
can plow three acres a day with three horses." That is what he does, and he 
does it with a walking plow because, he says, it is easier to walk than to 
ride.That, of course, is hardly a popular opinion, and Lancie is amused by 
the surprise it sometimes causes. 



A GOOD FARMER OF THE OLD SCHOOL 



123 



One spring, he says, after he had started plowing, he ordered some 
lime.When the trucker brought the first load, he stopped by the house to 
ask where to spread it. Mrs. Clippinger told him that Lancie was plowing, 
and pointed out to the field where Lancie could be seen walking in the fur- 
row behind his plow and team.The trucker was astonished: "Even the 
Amish ride!" 

In 1936, Lancie remembers, he plowed a hundred acres, sixty of them 
in sod, with two horses, Bob and Joe. Together, that team weighed about 
thirty-five hundred pounds.They were blacks. Lancie had been logging with 
them before he started plowing, and they were in good shape, ready to 
go.They plowed two acres a day, six days a week, for nearly nine weeks. It is 
the sort of thing, one guesses, that could have been done only because all 
the conditions were right: a strong young man, a tough team, a good sea- 
son. "Looked like, back then, there wasn't any bad weather," Lancie says, 
laughing. "You could work all the time." 

This farmer's extensive use of live horsepower is possible because his 
farm is the right size for it and because a sensible rotation of crops both 
reduces the acreage to be plowed each year and distributes the other field 
work so that not too much needs to be done at any one time. Of the farm's 
135 arable acres, approximately fifty-five will be in corn, forty in oats, and 
forty in alfalfa. Each of the crops will be grown on the same land two years 
in order to avoid buying alfalfa seed every year. 

The two-year-old alfalfa, turned under, supplies enough nitrogen for 
the first year of corn. In the second year, the corn crop receives a little com- 
mercial nitrogen. The routine application of fertilizer on the corn is 275 
pounds per acre of 10-10-20, drilled into the row with the planter. The oats 
are fertilized at the same rate as the corn, while the alfalfa field, because 
Lancie sells quite a bit of hay, receives 600 pounds per acre of 3-14-42 in 
two applications every year. The land is limed at a rate of two tons per acre 
every time it is plowed. Otherwise, for fertilization Lancie depends on 
manure from his cattle and horses. "That's what counts," he says. It counts 
because it pays but does not cost. He usually has enough manure to cover 
his corn ground every year. 

This system of management has not only maintained the productive 



124 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



capacity of the farm but has greatly improved it. Fourteen years ago, when 
Lancie began on it, the place was farmed out. The previous farmer had 
plowed it all and planted it all in corn year after year. When the farm sold 
in the fall of 1971, the corn crop, which was still standing, was bought by a 
neighboring farmer, who found it not worth picking. Lancie plowed it 
under the next spring. In order to have a corn crop that first year, he used 
900 pounds of fertilizer to the acre— 300 pounds of nitrogen and 600 of 
"straight analysis." After that, when his rotations and other restorative prac- 
tices had been established, he went to his present rate of 275 pounds of 10- 
10-20. The resulting rates of production speak well for good careThe corn 
has made 150 bushels per acre, Lancie says, "for a long time"; this year his 
oats made 109 bushels per acre, and he also harvested 11,000 fifty-pound 
bales of alfalfa hay from a forty-acre field (a per-acre yield of about seven 
tons) and sold 4,800 bales for $12,000. 

In addition to seed and fertilizer, Lancie purchases some insecticide 
and herbicide. This year his alfalfa was sprayed once for weevils, and he 
used a half-pint of 2-4-D per acre on his corn. The 2-4-D, he says, would 
not have been necessary if he had cultivated four times instead of twice. 
Using the chemical saved two cultivations that would have interfered with 
hay harvest. 

What is most significant about Lancie's management of his crops is 
that it gives his farm a degree of independence that is unusual in these 
times. The farm, first of all, is ordered and used according to its own na- 
ture and carrying capacity, not according to the dictates of farm policy, 
expert advice, or fluctuations of the economy. The possibility of solving 
one's economic problems by production alone is not, in Lancie's opinion, 
a good possibility. If you are losing money on the corn you produce, he 
points out, the more you produce the more you lose.That so many farm- 
ers continue to compensate for low grain prices by increasing production, 
at great cost to their farms and to themselves, is a sort of wonder to him. 
"The cheaper it is, the more they plow," he says. "I don't know what they 
mean." His own farm, by contrast, grows approximately the same acreages 
of the same crops every year, not because that is what the economy suppos- 
edly demands, but because that is what the land can produce at the least 
cost for the longest time. 



A GOOD FARMER OF THE OLD SCHOOL 



125 



Since the farm itself is so much the source of its own fertility and oper- 
ating energy, Lancie's use of purchased supplies can be minimal, selective, 
and nonaddictive. Because his cropping pattern and system of manage- 
ment are sound, Lancie can buy these things to suit his convenience. His 
total expense for 2-4-D for his corn this year, for example, was $56— a very 
small price to pay in order to have his hands and his mind free at haying 
time. The point, I think, is that he had a choice: He could choose to do 
what made the most sense. A further point is that he can quit using chem- 
icals and purchased fertilizer if it ever makes economic sense to do so. As 
a farmer, he is not addicted to these things. 

The conventional industrial farmer, on the other hand, is too often the 
prisoner of his own technology and methods and has no choice but to con- 
tinue to do as he has done, whatever the disadvantages. A farmer who has 
no fences cannot turn hogs in to harvest his corn when prices are low. A 
farmer who has invested heavily in a farrowing house and all the equip- 
ment that goes with it is stuck with that investment. If, for some reason, it 
ceases to be profitable for him to produce feeder pigs, he still has the far- 
rowing house, which is good for little else, and perhaps a debt on it as well. 
Thus, mental paralysis and economic slavery can be instituted on a farm by 
the farmer's technological choices. 

One of the main results of Lancie Clippinger's independence is ver- 
satility, enabling him to take advantage quickly of opportunities as they 
appear. Because he has invested in no expensive specialized equipment, he 
can change his ways to suit his wishes or his circumstances. That he did 
well raising and finishing shoats one year does not mean that he must con- 
tinue to raise them. Last year, for instance, he thought there was money to 
be made on skinny sows. He bought sixty-two at $100 a head, turned them 
into his cornfield, and, while they ate, he picked. "We all worked together," 
he says. The sows did a nearly perfect job of gleaning the field, and they 
brought $200 a head when he sold them. 

There is a direct economic payoff in this freedom of choice: It pays to 
be able to choose to substitute a team of horses for a tractor, or manure for 
fertilizer, or cultivation for herbicides. When you cultivate a field of corn, 
as Lancie says, "you're selling your labor"; in other words, you ensure a rela- 



126 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



tion between production and consumption that is proper because it makes 
sound economic sense. If the farmer does not achieve that proper relation 
on his farm, he will be a victim. When Lancie prepares his ground with 
plow and harrow and cultivates his crop instead of buying chemicals, he is 
a producer, not a consumer; he is selling his labor, not buying an expensive 
substitute for labor. Moreover, when he does this with a team of horses 
instead of buying fuel, he is selling his team's labor, not paying for an 
expensive substitute. When he uses his own corn, oats, and hay to replace 
petroleum, he is selling those feeds for a far higher return than he could get 
on the market. He and his horses are functioning, in effect, as solar con- 
verters, making usable and profitable the free sunlight that falls onto the 
farm.They are producing at home the energy, weed control, and fertility 
that other farmers are going broke trying to pay for. 

The industrial farmer consumes more than he produces and is a cap- 
tive consumer of the suppliers who have prospered by the ruination of such 
farmers. So far as the national economy is concerned, this kind of farmer 
exists only to provide cheap food and to enrich the agribusiness corpora- 
tions, at his own expense. 

Sometimes Lancie's intelligent methods and his habit of paying atten- 
tion yield unexpected dividends. The year after he hogged down the forty 
acres of corn with the 360 shoats, the field was covered with an excellent 
stand of alsike clover. "It was pretty," Lancie says, but he didn't know where 
it came from. He asked around in the neighborhood and discovered that 
the field had been in alsike seventeen years before. The seed had lain in 
the ground all that time, waiting for conditions to be right, and somehow 
the hogs had made them right.Thus, that year's very profitable corn har- 
vest, which had been so well planned, resulted in a valuable gift that 
nobody had planned-or could have planned. There is no recipe, so far as 
I know, for making such a thing happen. Obviously, though, a certain eli- 
gibility is required. It happened on Lancie's farm undoubtedly because he 
is the kind of farmer he is. If he had been plowing the whole farm every 
year and planting it all in corn, as his predecessor had, such a thing would 
not have happened. 

It is care, obviously, that makes the difference. The farm gives gifts 



A GOOD FARMER OF THE OLD SCHOOL 



127 



because it is given a chance to do so; it is not overcropped or overused. One 
of Lancie's kindnesses to his farm is his regular rotation of his crops; anoth- 
er is his keeping of livestock, which gives him not only the advantages I 
have already described but also permits him to make appropriate use of 
land not suited to row cropping. Like many farms in the allegedly flat corn 
belt, Lancie's farm includes some land that should be kept permanently 
grassed, and on his farm, unlike many, it is kept permanently grassed. He 
can afford this because he can make good use of it that way, without dam- 
aging it, for these thirty or so acres give him five hundred bales of bluegrass 
hay early in the year and, after that, months of pasture, at the cost only of 
a second clipping.The crop on that land does not need to be planted or cul- 
tivated, and it is harvested by the animals; it is therefore the cheapest feed 
on the place. 

Lancie Clippinger is as much in the business of growing crops and 
making money on them as any other farmer. But he is also in the business 
of making sense— making sense, that is, for himself, not for the oil, chemi- 
cal, and equipment companies, or for the banks. He is taking his own 
advice, and his advice comes from his experience and the experience of 
farmers like him, not from experts who are not farmers. For those reasons, 
Lancie Clippinger is doing all right. He is farming well and earning a liv- 
ing by it in a time when many farmers are farming poorly and making 
money for everybody but themselves. 

"I don't know what they mean," he says. "You'd think some in the 
bunch would use their heads a little bit." 



Charlie Fisher 



(1996) 



I don't imagine Charlie Fisher told me everything he has done, but in 
the day and a half I spent with him I did find out that he was raised on 
a truck farm, that for a while he rode bulls and exhibited a trick horse on 
the rodeo circuit, that as a young man he worked for a dairyman, and that 
later he had a dairy farm of his own. His interest in logging and in work- 
ing horses began while he was a hired hand in the dairy. In the winter, 
between milkings, he and his elderly employer spent their time in the 
woods at opposite ends of a crosscut sawwhich, Charlie says, made him 
tireder than it made the old dairyman.They cut some big timber and 
dragged out the logs with horses. The old dairyman saw that Charlie liked 
working horses and was good at it. And so it was that he became both a 
teamster and a logger. 

Though he tried other employment, those two early interests stayed 
with him, and he has spent many years logging with horses. There were 
times when he worked alone, cutting and skidding out the logs by him- self. 
Later, his son David began to work with him, skidding out the logs while 
Charlie cut. David, who is now twenty-two, virtually grew up in the woods. 
He started skidding logs with a team when he was nine, and he is still work- 
ing with his father, as both teamster and log cutter. 

Nine years ago, near Andover in northeast Ohio, Charlie Fisher and 
Jeff Green formed a company, Valley Veneer, which involves both a log- 
ging operation and a sawmill. Charlie buys the standing timber, marks the 
trees that are to be cut, and supervises the logging crews, while Jeff keeps 



129 



130 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



things going at the mill and markets the lumber. 

The mill employs eight or nine hands, and it saws three million board 
feet a year. It provides a local market for local timber. This obviously is good 
for the economy of the Andover neighborhood, but it also is good for the 
forest. By establishing the mill, Charlie and Jeff have invested in the neigh- 
borhood and formed a permanent connection to it, and so they have an 
inescapable interest in preserving the productivity of the local forest. Thus 
a local forest economy, if it is complex enough, will tend almost naturally 
to act as a conserver of the local forest ecosystem. Valley Veneer, according 
to Charlie and Jeff, has been warmly received into the neighborhood. The 
company deals with the only locally owned bank in the area. The bankers 
have been not only cooperative but also friendly, at times offering more 
help than Charlie and Jeff asked for. 

The mill yard is the neatest I have ever seen. The logs are sorted and 
ricked according to species. Veneer logs are laid down separately with one 
end resting on a pole, so that they can be readily examined by buyers. The 
mill crew is skillful in salvaging good lumber from damaged or inferior 
trees. This is extremely important, as is Jeff 's marketing of lumber from 
inferior species such as soft maple, for it means that the cutting in the 
woods is never limited to the best trees. Charlie marks the trees, knowing 
that whatever the woodland can properly yield— soft maple or fine furni- 
ture-quality cherry or trees damaged by disease or wind-can be sawed into 
boards and sold.The mill seemed to me an extraordinarily efficient place, 
where nothing of value is wasted. Twenty percent of the slabs are sold for 
firewood; the rest go to the chipper and are used for pulp. The sawdust is 
sold to farmers, who use it as bedding for animals. 

The woods operation-Charlie's end of the business— consists of three 
logging crews, each made up of one faller and two teamsters. Each of the 
teamsters works two horses on a logging cart or "logging arch." And so 
Charlie routinely employs nine men and twelve horses. At times, the cut- 
ter also will do some skidding, and this increases the number of teams in 
use. The three crews will usually be at work at three different sites. 

Mostly they log small, privately owned woodlots within a radius of forty 
or fifty miles. Charlie recently counted up and found that he had logged 



CHARLIE FISHER 131 



366 different tracts of timber in the last three years. And there are certain 
advantages to working on this scale. In a horse logging operation, it is best 
to limit the skidding distance to five or six hundred feet, though Charlie 
says they sometimes increase it to a thousand, and they can go somewhat 
farther in winter when snow or freezing weather reduces the friction. Big 
tracts, however, involve longer distances, and eventually it becomes neces- 
sary either to build a road for the truck or to use a bulldozer to move the 
logs from where the teamsters yard them in the woods to a second yarding 
place accessible from the highway. For this purpose, in addition to a log 
truck equipped with a hydraulic loading boom,Valley Veneer owns two 
bulldozers, one equipped with a fork, one with a blade, and both with 
winches. Even so, about 98 percent of the logs are moved with horses. 

The logging crews work the year round and in all weather except pour- 
ing rain. The teamsters, who furnish their own teams and equipment, 
receive forty dollars per thousand board feet. Two of his teamsters, Charlie 
says, make more than thirty thousand dollars a year each. 

The logging arch, in comparison to a mechanical skidder, is a very 
forthright piece of equipment. Like the forecart that is widely used for field 
work, it is simply a way to provide a drawbar for a team of horses. 

There are a number of differences in design, but the major difference 
is that the logging arch's drawbar is welded on edge-up and has slots in- 
stead of holes.The slots are made so as to catch and hold the links of a log 
chain. Each cart carries an eighteen-foot chain with a grab hook at each 
end. Four metal hooks (which Charlie calls "log grabs," but which are also 
called "J-hooks" or "logging dogs") are linked to rings and strung on the 
chain, thus permitting the cart to draw as many as four logs at a time. The 
chain can also be used at full length if necessary to reach a hard-to- get-to 
log. Larger logs require the use of tongs, which the teamsters also carry with 
them, or two grabs driven into the log on opposite sides. The carts are 
equipped also with a cant hook and a "skipper" with which to drive the 
grabs into the log and knock them out again. 

The slotted drawbar permits the chain to be handily readjusted as the 
horses work a log into position for skidding. When the log is ready to go, 
it is chained as closely as possible to the drawbar, so that when the hors- 



132 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



es tighten the fore end of the log is raised off the ground. This is the 
major efficiency of the logging arch: By thus raising the log, the arch both 
keeps it from digging and reduces its friction against the ground by more 
than half. 

We watched a team drag out a twelve-foot log containing about 330 
board feet. They were well loaded but were not straining. Charlie says that 
a team can handle up to five or six hundred board feet. For bigger logs, they 
use an additional team or a bulldozer. A good teamster can skid 3,000 to 
3,500 board feet a day in small logs. The trick, Charlie says, is to know what 
your horses can do, and then see that they do that much on every pull. 
Overload, and you're resting too much. Underload, and you're wasting 
energy and time. The important thing is to keep loaded and keep moving. 

Charlie Fisher is a man of long experience in the woods and extensive 
knowledge of the timber business and of logging technology. He has no 
prejudice against mechanical equipment as such, but uses it readily accord- 
ing to need; for a time, during his thirties, he used mechanical skidders. 
That this man greatly prefers horses for use in the woods is therefore of 
considerable interest. I asked him to explain. 

His first reason, and the most important, is one I'd heard before from 
draft horsemen: "I've always liked horses." Charlie and David are clearly 
the sort of men who can't quite live without horses. Between them, they 
own six excellent, very large Belgian geldings and two Belgian mares. 
Charlie, as he explained, owns three and a half horses, and David four and 
a half. The two halves, fortunately, belong to the same horse, which 
Charlie and David own in partnership. Charlie has long been an enthusi- 
astic participant in pulling contests, and David has followed in his father's 
footsteps in the arena as in the woods. Last season, David participated in 
twenty-three contests and Charlie in five, which for him was many fewer 
than usual. Charlie and his wife, Becky, showed us several shelves crowd- 
ed with trophies, many of which were David's. It looked to me like they are 
going to need more shelves. Charlie and Becky are very proud of David, 
who is an accomplished logger and horseman. David, Charlie says, is an 
exceptionally quiet hand with a team-unlike Charlie, who confessed, "I 
holler." Since they would have the horses anyhow, Charlie said, they might 



CHARLIE FISHER 133 



as well put them to work in the woods, which keeps them fit and allows 
them to earn their keep. 

Charlie's second reason for using horses in the woods, almost as impor- 
tant as the first, is that he likes the woods, and horses leave the woods in 
better condition than a skidder. A team and a logging arch require a much 
narrower roadway than a skidder; unlike a skidder, they don't bark trees; 
and they leave their skidding trails far less deeply rutted. "The horse," 
Charlie says, "will always be the answer to good logging in a woods." 

A third attractive feature of the horse economy in the woods is that the 
horse logger both earns and spends his money in the local community, 
whereas the mechanical skidder siphons money away from the community 
and into the hands of large corporate suppliers. Moreover, the horse log- 
ger's kinder treatment of the woods will, in the long run, yield an econom- 
ic benefit. 

And, finally, horses work far more cheaply and cost far less than a skid- 
der, thus requiring fewer trees to be cut per acre, and so permitting the 
horse logger to be more selective and conservative. 

(Another issue involved in the use of horses for work is that of energy 
efficiency. Legs are more efficient than wheels over rough ground— some- 
thing that will quickly be apparent to you if you try riding a bicycle over a 
plowed field.) 

Well ahead of the logging crews, Charlie goes into the woods to mark 
the trees that are to be cut. Except when he is working for a "developer" 
who is going to clear the land, Charlie never buys or marks trees with the 
idea of taking every one that is marketable. His purpose is to select a num- 
ber of trees, often those that need cutting because they are diseased or 
damaged or otherwise inferior, which will provide a reasonable income to 
landowner and logger alike, without destroying the wood-making capacity 
of the forest.The point can best be understood by considering the differ- 
ence between a year's growth added to a tree four- teen inches in diameter 
and that added to a tree four inches in diameter. Clear-cutting or any other 
kind of cutting that removes all the trees of any appreciable size radically 
reduces the wood-making capacity of the forest. After such a cutting, in 
Charlie's part of the country, it will be sixty to a hundred years before 



134 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



another cutting can be made. Of a clear-cut woodland that adjoined one 
of his own tracts, Charlie said, "In fifty years there still won't be a decent 
log in it." 

Charlie does not believe that such practices are good for the forest or 
the people— or, ultimately, for the timber business. He stated his interest 
forthrightly in economic terms, but his is the right kind of economics: "I 
hope maybe there'll be trees here for my son to cut in ten or twenty years." 
If you don't overdo the cutting, he says, a woodland can yield a cash crop 
every ten to fifteen years. We looked at one tract of twenty acres on which 
Charlie had marked about 160 trees and written the owner a check for 
$23,000. Charlie described this as "a young piece of timber," and he said 
that it "definitely" could be logged again in ten years-at which time he 
could both take more and leave more good trees than he will take and leave 
at this cutting. 

Owners of wooded land should consider carefully the economics of 
this twenty-acre tract. If it is selectively and carefully logged every ten years, 
as Charlie says it can be, then every acre will earn $1,150 every ten years, 
or $115 per year. And this comes to the landowner without expense or 
effort. (These particular figures, of course, apply only to this particular 
woodlot. Some tracts might be more productive, others less.) We looked at 
marked woodlands, at woodlands presently being logged, and finally, at the 
end of the second day of our visit, at a woodland that one of Charlie's crews 
had logged three years ago. The last, a stand predominantly of hard and 
soft maples, provided convincing evidence of the good sense of Charlie's 
kind of forestry. Very few of the remaining trees had been damaged by trees 
felled during the logging. I saw not a single tree that had been barked by a 
skidded log.The skid trails had completely healed over; there was no sign 
of erosion. And, most striking, the woodland was still ecologically intact. It 
was still a diverse, uneven-aged stand of trees, many of which were over six- 
teen inches in diameter. We made a photograph of three trees, standing 
fairly close together, which varied in diameter from seventeen to twenty- 
one inches. After logging, the forest is still a forest, and it will go on mak- 
ing wood virtually without interruption or diminishment. It seems perfect- 
ly reasonable to think that, if several generations of owners were so 
inclined, this sort of forestry could eventually result in an "old growth" for- 



CHARLIE FISHER 135 



est that would have produced a steady income for two hundred years. 

I was impressed by a good many things during my visit with Charlie 
Fisher, but what impressed me most is the way that Charlie's kind of log- 
ging achieves a complex fairness or justice to the several interests that are 
involved: the woods, the landowner, the timber company, the woods crews 
and their horses. 

Charlie buys standing trees, and he marks every tree he buys.Within a 
fairly narrow margin of error, Charlie knows what he is buying, and the 
landowner knows what he is getting paid for. When Charlie goes in to 
mark the trees, he is thinking not just about what he will take, but also 
about what he will leave. He sees the forest as it is, and he sees the forest as 
it will be when the logging job is finished. I think he sees it too as it will be 
in ten or fifteen or twenty years, when David or another logger will return 
to it. By this long-term care, he serves the forest and the landowner as well 
as himself. As he marks the trees he is thinking also of the logging crew that 
will soon be there. He marks each tree that is to be cut with a slash of red 
paint. Sometimes, where he has seen a leaning deadfall or a dead limb or 
a flaw in the trunk, he paints an arrow above the slash, and this means 
"Look up!" The horses, like the men, are carefully borne in mind. 
Everywhere, the aim is to do the work in the best and the safest way. 

Moreover, these are not competing interests, but seem rather to merge 
into one another. Thus one of Charlie's economic standards— "I hope maybe 
there'll be trees here for my son to cut in ten or twenty years"— becomes, in 
application, an ecological standard. And the ecological standard becomes, 
again, an economic standard as it proves to be good for business. 

Most landowners, Charlie says, care how their woodlands are logged. 
Though they may need the income from their trees, they don't want to sac- 
rifice the health or beauty of their woods in order to get it. Charlie's way of 
logging recommends itself to such people; he does not need to advertise. 
As we were driving away from his house on the morning of our second day, 
one of the neighbors waved us to a stop. This man makes his living selling 
firewood, and he had learned of two people who wanted their woodlands 
logged by a horse logger.That is the way business comes to him, Charlie 
said. Like other horse loggers, he has all the work he can do, and more. It 



136 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



has been ten years since he has had to hunt for woodlots to log. He said, 
"Everybody else has buyers out running the roads, looking for timber." But 
he can't buy all that he is offered. 

I don't know that I have ever met a man with more enthusiasms than 
Charlie Fisher. I have mentioned already his abounding interest in his fam- 
ily, in forestry, and in working and pulling horses, but I have neglected to 
say that he is also a coon hunter. This seems to me a most revealing detail. 
Here is a man who makes his living by walking the woods all day, and who 
then entertains himself by walking the woods at night. 

He told me that he had a list of several things he had planned to do 
when he retired, but that now, at sixty-six, he is busier than ever. 

"Well," I said, "you seem to be enjoying it." 

"Oh," he said, "I love it!" 



A Talent for Necessity 



(1980) 



IN THE DAYS when the Southdown ram was king of the sheep pastures 
and the show ring, Henry Besuden of Vinewood Farm in Clark County, 
Kentucky, was perhaps the premier breeder and showman of Southdown 
sheep in the United States. The list of his winnings at major shows would 
be too long to put down here, but the character of his achievement can be 
indicated by his success in showing carload lots of fat lambs in the Chicago 
International Livestock Exposition. Starting in 1946, he sent eighteen car- 
loads to the International, and won the competition twelve times. "I had 
'em fat," he says, remembering. "I had 'em good." Such was the esteem and 
demand for his stock among fellow breeders that in 1954 he sold a yearling 
ram for $1,200, then a record price for a Southdown. 

One would imagine that such accomplishments must have rested on 
the very best of Bluegrass farmland. But the truth, nearly opposite to that, 
is much more interesting. "If I'd inherited good land," Henry Besuden says, 
"I'd probably have been just another Bluegrass farmer." 

What he inherited, in fact, was 632 acres of rolling land, fairly steep in 
places, thin soiled even originally, and by the time he got it, worn-out, 
"corned to death." His grandfather would rent the land out to corn, two 
hundred acres at a time, and not even get up to see where it would be plant- 
ed—even though "it was understood to be the rule that renters ruined the 
land." By the time Henry Besuden was eight years old both his mother and 
father were dead, and the land was farmed by tenants under the trusteeship 
of a Cincinnati bank. When the farm came to him in 1927, it was heavily 



137 



138 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



encumbered by debt and covered with gullies, some of which were deep 
enough to hide a standing man. 

And so Mr. Besuden began his life as a farmer with the odds against 
him. But his predicament became his education and, finally, his triumph. 
"I was lucky," he told Grant Cannon of The Farm Quarterly in 1951. "I found 
that I had some talent for doing the things I had to do. I had to improve 
the farm or starve to death; and I had to go into the sheep business because 
sheep were the only animals that could have lived off the farm." 

Now seventy-six years old and not in the best of health, Mr. Besuden 
has not owned a sheep for several years, but he speaks of them with exact 
remembrance and exacting intelligence; he is one of the best talkers I have 
had the luck to listen to. How did he get started with sheep? "I was told 
they'd eat weeds and briars," he says, looking sideways through pipesmoke 
to see if I get the connection, for the connection between sheep and land 
is the critical one for him.The history of his sheep and the history of his 
farm are one history, and it is his own. 

Having only talent and necessity— and unusual energy and determina- 
tion-Mr. Besuden set about the restoration of his ravaged fields. There was 
no Soil Conservation Service then, but a young man in his predicament 
was bound to get plenty of advice. To check erosion he first tried building 
rock dams across the gullies.That wasn't satisfactory; the dams did catch 
some dirt, but then the fields were marred by half-buried rock walls that 
interfered with work. He tried huge windrows of weeds and brush to the 
same purpose, but that was not satisfactory either. 

Some of the worst gullies he eventually had to fill with a bulldozer. But 
his main erosion-stopping tool turned out, strangely enough, to be the 
plow, the tool that in the wrong hands had nearly ruined the farm, in the 
right hands healed it. Starting at the edge of a gulley he would run a back- 
furrow up one side and down the other, continuing to plow until he had 
completed a sizable land. And then he would start at the gulley again, turn- 
ing the furrows inward as before. He repeated this process until what had 
been a ditch had become a saucer, so that the runoff, rather than concen- 
trating its force in an abrasive torrent, would be shallowly dispersed over as 
wide an area as possible. This, as he knew, had been the method of the 



A TALENT FOR NECESSITY 



139 



renters to prepare the gullied land for yet another crop of corn. For them, 
it had been a temporary remedy; he made it a permanent one. 

Nowadays Kentucky fescue 31 would be the grass to sow on such places, 
but fescue was not available then. Mr. Besuden used small grains, timothy, 
sweet clover, Korean lespedeza. He used mulches, and he did not overlook 
the usefulness of what he knew for certain would grow on his land— weeds: 
"Briars are a good thing for a little hollow." In places he planted thickets of 
black locust— a native leguminous tree that would serve four purposes: hold 
the land, encourage grass to grow, provide shade for livestock, and produce 
posts. But his highest praise is given to the sweet clover which he calls "the 
best land builder I've ever run into. It'll open up clay, and throw a lot of 
nitrogen into the ground." The grass would come then, and the real heal- 
ing would start. 

Once the land was in grass, his policy generally was to leave it in grass. 
Only the best-laying, least vulnerable land was broken for tobacco, the 
region's major money crop then as now. Even today, I noticed, he sees that 
his fields are plowed very conservatively. The plowlands are small and care- 
fully placed, leaving out thin places and waterways. 

The basic work of restoration continued for twenty-three years. By 
1950 the scars were grassed over, and the land was supporting one of the 
great Southdown flocks of the time. But it was not healed. What was there 
is gone, and Henry Besuden knows that it will be a long time building 
back. "Tain't in good shape, yet," he told an interviewer in 1978. 

And so if Mr. Besuden built a reputation as one of the best of live- 
stock showmen, the focus of his interest was nevertheless not the show ring 
but the farm. It would be true, it seems, to say that he became a master 
sheepman and shepherd as one of the ways of becoming a master farmer. 
For this reason, his standards of quality were never frivolous or freakish, as 
show-ring standards have sometimes been accused of being, but insistently 
practical. He never forgot that the purpose of a sheep is to produce a living 
for the farmer and to put good meat on the table: "When they asked me, 
'What do you consider a perfect lamb?' I said, 'One a farmer can make 
money on!' The foundation has to be the commercial flock." And he wrote 
in praise of the Southdown ram that "he paid his rent." 



140 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



But it was perhaps even more characteristic of him to write in 1945 
that "one very important thing is that sheep are land builders," and to plead 
for their continued inclusion in farm livestock programs. He had seen the 
handwriting on the wall: the new emphasis on row cropping and "produc- 
tion" which in the years after World War II would radically alter the bal- 
ance of crops and animals on farms, and which, as he feared, would help 
to destroy the sheep business in his own state. (In 1947, Mr. Besuden's 
county of Clark had twenty-four breeding flocks of Southdowns, and 
30,000 head of grade ewes. That is more than remain now in the whole 
state of Kentucky.) What he called for instead— and events are rapidly prov- 
ing him right-was "a long-time program of land building" by which he 
meant a way of farming based on grass and forage crops, which would build 
up and maintain reserves of fertility. And in that kind of farming, he was 
prepared to insist, because he knew, sheep would have an important place. 

"I think," he wrote in his series of columns, "Sheep Sense," published 
in The Sheepman in 1945 and 1946, "the fertilizing effect of sheep on the 
farm has never received the attention it deserves. As one who has had to 
farm poor land where the least amount of fertilizer shows up plainly, I have 
noticed that on land often thought too poor for cattle the sheep do well 
and in time benefit the crops and grass to such an extent that other stock 
can then be carried. I have seldom seen sheep bed down for the night on 
anything but high land, and their droppings are evenly scattered on the pas- 
ture while grazing, so that no vegetation is killed." 

What he wanted was "a way of farming compatible with nature"; this 
was the constant theme of his work, and he followed it faithfully, both in his 
pleasure in the lives and events of nature and in his practical solutions to 
the problems of farming and soil husbandry. He was never too busy to 
appreciate, and to praise, the spiritual by-products, as he called them, of 
farm life. Nor was he too busy to attend to the smallest needs of his land. 
At one time, for example, he built "two small houses on skids," each of 
which would hold twenty-five bales of hay.These could be pulled to places 
where the soil was thin, where the hay would be fed out, and then moved 
on to other such places. (In the spring they could be used to raise chickens.) 

"It's good to have Nature working for you," he says. "She works for a 



A TALENT FOR NECESSITY 



141 



minimum wage." But in reading his "Sheep Sense" columns, one realizes 
that he not only did not separate the spiritual from the practical, but insist- 
ed that they cannot be separated: "This thing of soil conservation involves 
more than laying out a few terraces and diversion ditches and sowing to 
grass and legumes, it also involves the heart of the man managing the land. 
If he loves his soil he will save it." Once, he says, he thought of numbering 
his fields, but decided against it— "That didn't seem fair to them"— for each 
has its own character and potential. 

As a rule, he would have 400 head of ewes in two flocks— a flock of reg- 
istered Southdowns and a flock of "Western" commercial ewes. After lamb- 
ing, he would be running something in the neighborhood of 1,000 head. 
To handle so many sheep on a diversified farm required a great deal of care, 
and Mr. Besuden's system of management, worked out with thorough 
understanding and attention to detail, is worth the interest and reflection 
of any raiser of livestock. 

It was a system intended, first of all, to get the maximum use of forage. 
This rested on what he understands to be a sound principle of livestock 
farming and soil conservation, but it was forced upon him by the poor 
quality of his land. He had to keep row cropping to a minimum, and if that 
meant buying grain, then he would buy it. But he did not buy much. He 
usually fed, he told me, one pound of corn per ewe per day for sixty days. 
But in "Sheep Sense" for December 1945, he wrote: "One-half pound grain 
with three pounds legume hay should do the job, starting with the hay and 
adding the grain later." He creep-fed his early lambs, but took them off 
grain as soon as pasture was available. In "Sheep Sense," March 1946, he 
stated flatly that "creep-feeding after good grass arrives does not pay." 

Grain, then, he considered not a diet, but a supplement, almost an 
emergency ration, to ensure health and growth in the flock during the time 
when he had no pasture. It must be remembered that he was talking about 
a kind of sheep bred to make efficient use of pasture and hay, and that the 
market then favored that kind. In the decades following World War II, 
cheap energy and cheap grain allowed interest to shift to the larger breeds 
of sheep and larger slaughter lambs that must be grain-fed. But now with 
the cost of energy rising, pushing up the cost of grain, and the human con- 



142 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



sumption of grain rising with the increase of population, Henry Besuden's 
sentence of a generation ago resounds with good sense: "Due to the short- 
age of grain throughout the world, the sheep farmer needs to study the pos- 
sibilities of grass fattening." 

Those, anyhow, were the possibilities that he was studying. And the 
management of pasture, the management of sheep on pasture, was his art. 

In the fall he would select certain pastures close to the barn to be used 
for late grazing. This is what is now called "stockpiling"— which, he points 
out, is only a new word for old common sense. It was sometimes possible, 
in favorable years, to keep the ewes on grass all through December, feeding 
"very little hay" and "a small amount of grain." Sometimes he sowed rye 
early to provide late fall pasture and so extend the grazing season. 

His ewes were bred to lamb in January and February. He fed good 
clover or alfalfa hay, and from about the middle of January to about the 
middle of March he gave the ewes their sixty daily rations of grain. In mid- 
March the grain-feeding ended, and ewes and lambs went out on early pas- 
ture of rye which had been sown as a cover crop on the last year's tobacco 
patches. "A sack of Balboa rye sown in the early fall," he wrote, "is worth 
several sacks of feed fed in the spring and is much cheaper." From the rye 
they went to the clover fields where tobacco had grown two years before. 
From the clover they were moved onto the grass pastures. The market 
lambs were sold straight off the pastures, at eighty to eighty-five pounds, 
starting the first of May. 

After fescue became available, Mr. Besuden made extensive use of it in 
his pastures. But he feels that this grass, though an excellent land conserv- 
es is not nutritious or palatable enough to make the best sheep pasture, 
and so he took pains to diversify his fescue stands with timothy and 
legumes. His favorite pasture legume is Korean lespedeza, though he joins 
in the fairly common complaint that it is less vigorous and productive now 
than it used to be. He has also used red clover, alsike, ladino, and birdsfoot 
trefoil. He says that he had trouble getting his ewes with lamb in the first 
heat when they were bred on clover pastures, but that he never had this 
trouble on lespedeza. 

His pastures were regularly reseeded to legumes, usually in March, the 



A TALENT FOR NECESSITY 



143 



sheep tramping in the seed, and he found this method of "renovation" to 
be as good as any. The pastures were clipped twice during the growing sea- 
son, sometimes oftener, to keep the growth vigorous and uniform. 

The key to efficient management of sheep on pasture is paying atten- 
tion, and it was important to Mr. Besuden that he should be on horseback 
among his sheep in the early mornings. The sheep would be out of the 
shade then, grazing, and he could study their condition and the condition 
of the field. He speaks of the "bloom" of a pasture, referring to a certain 
freshness of appearance made by new, tender growth sprigging up through 
the old.When that bloom is gone, he thinks, the sheep should be moved. 
The move from a stale pasture to a fresh one can lengthen the grazing time 
by as much as two hours a day. He believes also that lambs do best when 
the flock is not too large. That is because sheep tend to bunch together 
when grazing, the least vigorous lambs coming last and having to feed on 
grass mouthed over and rejected by the others. He saw to it that his pas- 
tures were amply provided with shade, and he knew that the shade needed 
to be well placed: "I think the best lamb-growing pastures I have are the 
ones where the shade is close to the water. I have seen times during July 
and August when sheep would not leave the shade and go to water if the 
shade and water happened to be at opposite ends of a large field." 

The crisis of the shepherd's year, of course, is lambing time. That is the 
time that the year's work stands or falls by. And because it usually takes 
place in cold weather, the success of lambing is almost as dependent on the 
shepherd's facilities as on his knowledge. The lambing barn at Vinewood is 
an instructive embodiment of Mr. Besuden's understanding of his work 
and his gift for order. He gives a good description of it himself in one of 
his columns: 

Practically all the lambing here atVinewood in recent years has been 
in a barn especially made for the purpose, shiplap (tongue groove) box- 
ing with a low loft and a window in each bent. The east end of the 
barn [away from the prevailing winds] is rarely ever closed, a gate being 
used. Often in extremely cold weather the temperature can be raised fif- 
teen or twenty degrees by the heat from the sheep. Some thirty feet out 
in the front and extending the width of the barn [is] a heavy layer of 



144 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



rock. . . . This prevents the muddy place that often appears at the barn 
door and . . . pulls at the sheep as they walk through it, causing slipped 
lambs. Also at the entrance . . . a locust post is half embedded across 
the door.This serves as a protection in case of dogs trying to dig under 
the door or gate and helps to hold the bedding in the barn as the sheep 
go out. Any kind of a sill that is too high or causes the heavy-in-lamb 
ewes to jump or strain to cross is too risky. 

The barn is admirably laid out, with pens, chutes, and gates to permit the 
feeding, handling, sorting, and loading of a large number of sheep with the 
least trouble. There were lambing pens for forty ewes. There was also a 
small room with pens that could be heated by a stove. Above each pen was 
a red wooden "button" that could be turned down to indicate that a ewe 
was near to lambing or for any other reason in need of close attention. 
These were used when Mr. Besuden had an experienced helper to share the 
nighttime duty with him. "They saved a lot of cold midnight talk," he says. 

But experienced help was not always available, and then he would have 
to work through the days and nights of lambing alone. Staying awake 
would get to be a problem. Sometimes, sitting beside one of the pens, wait- 
ing for a ewe to lamb, he would tie a string from one of her hind legs to his 
wrist. When her labor pains came and she began to shift around, she 
would tug the string and he would wake up and tend to her. 

And so the talent for what he "had to do" was in large measure the abil- 
ity to bear the good outcome in mind: to envision, in spite of rocks and gul- 
lies, the good health of the fields; to foresee in the pregnant ewes and the 
advancing seasons a good crop of lambs. And it was the ability to carry in 
his head for nearly half a century the ideal character and pattern of the 
Southdown, and to measure his animals relentlessly against it— an ability, 
rare enough, that marked him as a master stockman. 

He told me a story that suggests very well the distinction and the effect 
of that ability. On one of his trips to the International he competed against 
a western sheepman who had selected his carload of fifty fat lambs out of 
ten thousand head. 

After the Vinewood carload had won the class, this gentleman came up 



A TALENT FOR NECESSITY 



145 



and asked: "How many did you pick yours from, Mr. Besuden?" 
"About seventy-five." 

"Well," the western breeder said, "I guess it's better to have the right sev- 
enty-five than the wrong ten thousand." 

But the ability to recognize the right seventy-five is worthless by it self. 
Just as necessary is the ability to do the work and to pay attention.To pay 
attention, above all-that is another of the persistent themes of Mr. 
Besuden's talk and of his life. He is convinced that paying attention pays, 
and this sets him apart from the mechanized "modern" farmers who are 
pushed to accept more responsibility than they can properly meet, and to 
work at freeway speeds. He wrote in his column of the importance of "lit- 
tle things done on time." He said that they paid, but he knew that people 
did them for more than pay. 

He told me also about a farmer who couldn't scrape the manure off his 
shoes until he came to a spot that was bare of grass. "That's what I mean," 
he said. "You have to keep it on your mind." 



Elmer Lapp's Place 



(1979) 



THE THIRTY cows come up from the pasture and go one by one into 
the barn. Most of them are Guernseys, but there are also a few red 
Holsteins and a couple of Jerseys. They go to their places and wait while 
their neck chains are fastened. And then Elmer Lapp, his oldest son, and 
his youngest daughter go about the work of feeding, washing, and milking. 

In the low, square room, lighted by a row of big windows, a radio is qui- 
etly playing music. Several white cats sit around waiting for milk to be 
poured out for them from the test cup. Two collie dogs rest by the wall, out 
of the way. Several buff Cochin bantams are busily foraging for whatever 
waste grain can be found in the bedding and in the gutters. Overhead, fas- 
tened to the ceiling joists, are many barn swallow nests, their mud cups 
empty now at the end of October. Two rusty-barreled .22 rifles are propped 
in window frames, kept handy to shoot English sparrows, and there are no 
sparrows to be seen. Outside the door a bred heifer and a rather timeworn 
pet jenny are eating their suppers out of feed boxes. Beyond, on the stream 
that runs through the pasture, wild ducks are swimming. The shadows have 
grown long under the low-slanting amber light. 

This is a farm of eighty-three acres that has been in the Lapp family 
since 1915, five years before Elmer Lapp was born, and he has been here 
all his life. Three years ago a new house was built for Mr. Lapp's oldest son, 
who is his farming partner, father and son doing all the carpentry them- 
selves. Except for the four or five days a month that the son works off the 
farm, the two households take their living from this place, plus fourteen 



147 



148 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



acres of rented pasture and forty acres of hay harvested on the shares on a 
farm some distance away.They are farming then, all told, 117 acres. 

Because this farm is in Lancaster County, Pennsylvania, in an enclave 
of Amish and Mennonite farms that has become a "tourist attraction," the 
Lapps are able to supplement their agricultural income by selling farm 
tours, chicken barbecue, and homemade ice cream to busloads of school- 
children and tourists. But as profitable a sideline as this undoubtedly is, it 
should not distract from the economic and ecological good health of the 
farm operation itself. At a time when so many small farms are struggling 
or failing, it may be easy to suspect that this farm survives by dependence 
on the tourist industry. I do not think so. Here, at least, the opposite 
would seem to be true: The sideline succeeds because the main enterprise 
is a success. 

Standing in the stanchion barn while the cows are being milked, I am 
impressed by how quietly the work is done. No voice is raised.There is 
never a sudden or violent motion. Although the work is quickly done, no 
one rushes. And finally comes the realization that the room is quiet 
because it is orderly: All the creatures there, people and animals alike, are 
at rest within a pattern deeply familiar to them all. That evening and the 
day following, as I extend my acquaintance with the farm and with Elmer 
Lapp's understanding of it, I see that quiet chore time as a nucleus or 
gathering point in a pattern that includes the whole farm. The farm is 
thriving because what I would call its structural problems have been satis- 
factorily solved. The patterns necessary to its life have been perceived and 
worked out. 

THE COMMERCIAL PATTERN 

IN ITS COMMERCIAL aspect, this is a livestock farm. Its crops are not grown 
to sell, but to feed animals. The main enterprises are the thirty-cow 
dairy, and eleven Belgian brood mares. 

Mr. Lapp's dairy herd is made up mainly of Guernseys because, he says, 
"Big cows eat too much. "And the richer milk of the Guernseys brings a pre- 
mium price. His few Holsteins are red ones, because their milk is richer than 
that of the blacks.Their milk "tests with the Guernseys'," Mr. Lapp says. 



ELMER LAPP'S PLACE 



149 



He now sells manufacturing milk to the people who make Hershey 
chocolate. He used to ship Grade A, but quit, he says, because "The Grade 
A guys got under my hide. You could never satisfy them. They always want- 
ed something else." At several points in our conversation Mr. Lapp showed 
this sort of independence. He is not a man to put up long with anything 
he does not like. And this, again, I take as an indication of his success as a 
farmer. He is independent because he can afford to be. 

At present, in addition to the thirty milking cows, he has twelve 
heifers, six of which he has just started on the bucket. He likes to have a 
couple of heifers coming fresh each year. He sells his bull calves as babies. 
His heifer calves are started on milk replacer, which he considers better for 
the purpose than milk. They are given two quarts at a feeding. 

When I ask Mr. Lapp what a farmer could expect to make from a farm 
of this size, managed as this one is, he replies by saying that he sells $20,000 
to $30,000 worth of milk each year. Last year his dairy grossed $25,000. 

I ask him how much of that was net. 

He can't tell me exactly, he says. He bought $5,000 worth of supple- 
ments, but that included extra feed for his chickens, horses, and calves. 
And, of course, some of the expense was offset by the sale of bull calves and 
heifers. Aside from this information, he describes his income by saying "I 
pay taxes." 

Mr. Lapp offers no information about his income from his horses. But 
the market for draft horses is booming, and one must suppose that the 
Lapp farm is sharing in the payoff. Last year Mr. Lapp sold nine head. This 
past season he has bred eleven mares. He also has an income from his stal- 
lion who serves, he says, "all the outside mares I can handle." Besides the 
brood mares and the stallion, he presently has on hand a two-year-old filly, 
two yearling fillies, two yearling stud colts, and two foals. 

He prefers the draftier type of Belgians, but wants them long-legged 
enough to walk fast, and because he works his horses he is attentive to the 
need for good feet. Along with those practical virtues, he likes his horses to 
show a good deal of refinement, and in selecting breeding stock pays par- 
ticular attention to heads and necks. Among his mares are several that are 
half or full sisters, and this gives his horses a very noticeable uniformity of 



150 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



both color and conformation. 

Because for some reason his land will not produce oats of satisfactory 
quality, Mr. Lapp grows barley for his horses. If barley was good enough 
horse feed for King Solomon, he says, it is good enough for him. He crimps 
or grinds the barley and adds molasses. 

Unlike many horsemen, Mr. Lapp has no elaborate lore or procedure 
for breeding mares. He serves a mare only once, on whatever day he notices 
that she is in heat. And he sees no sense in pregnancy tests or examina- 
tions. Even so, he says, he has no trouble getting mares to conceive-or cows 
either, except with artificial insemination. 

But just because his major income is from dairy cows and brood mares, 
Mr. Lapp does not shut his eyes to other opportunities. "You stay awake," 
he says. He knows what will sell, and so far as his place and time allow he 
has it for sale. He feeds three hundred guineas at a time in a small loft. He 
raises and sells collie pups. He sells his surplus of eggs and honey. Even the 
barn cats contribute their share of income, for when he gets too many he 
sells the surplus at the local sale barn. 

THE PATTERN OF SUBSISTENCE 

THOUGH THE Lapp farm is commercially profitable its balance sheet 
would fall far short of accounting for the life of the place, or even for 
its economy. 

Elmer Lapp is eminently a traditional farmer in the sense that his farm 
is his home, his life, and his way of life— not just his "work place" or his 
"job." For that reason, though his farm produces a cash income, that is not 
all it produces, and some of what it produces cannot be valued in cash. 

In obedience to traditional principle, the Lapps take their subsistence 
from the farm, and they are as attentive to the production of what they eat 
as to the production of what they sell. The farm is expected to make a prof- 
it, but it must make sense too, and a part of that sense is that it must feed 
the farmers. And so a pattern of subsistence joins, and at certain points 
overlaps, the commercial pattern. 

For instance, the Lapps drink their own milk. I know that a lot of 
dairying families buy their milk at the grocery store, and so I ask Mr. Lapp 



ELMER LAPP S PLACE 



151 



why he doesn't buy milk for his own household. 

He answers unhesitatingly: "I don't like that slop." 

He also grows a garden. He has an orchard of apple, peach, and plum 
trees for fruit, and for blossoms for his bees. He is feeding four hogs, 
bought cheaply because they were runts, to slaughter for home use. He 
slaughters his own beef, and produces his own poultry, eggs, and honey. 

He is also aware that the pattern of subsistence is a community pat- 
tern. He says, for instance, that he deals with the little country stores rather 
than the supermarkets in the city. The little country stores support the life 
of the community, whereas the supermarkets support "the economy" at the 
expense of communities. 

THE PATTERNS OF SOILHUSBANDRY 
T T NDERLYING THE PATTERNS of the farm's productivity is a stewardship 



V__/ of the soil at all points knowledgeable, disciplined, and responsible. 
And this stewardship, necessarily, has evolved its own appropriate patterns. 

In any year, Mr. Lapp will have twenty-two acres in corn (twelve for 
silage, ten to husk), twenty-five acres in clover or alfalfa, ten acres in bar- 
ley or rye, and the rest in permanent pasture. The rotation is, mainly, as 
follows: 

First year: Corn for husking. 
Second year: Silage corn. 

Third year: Barley, planted in preceding fall, with clover and tim- 
othy sowed broadcast onto frozen ground in spring. After the 
barley is harvested, the field produces one cutting of hay. 
Fourth year: Clover and timothy (two cuttings). 
Fifth year: Back to corn. 

This pattern is varied in two ways. Where alfalfa is sowed instead of 
clover, the field is left in sod for three or four years instead of two. And 
when rye is sowed instead of barley, the rye is flail-chopped in the 
bloom and baled for bedding, and the land is returned to silage corn 
the same year. 




152 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



The whole farm is covered with manure each year, at a rate, Mr. Lapp 
figures, of about eight tons per acre. And care is taken to get the manure 
on at the right time. I ask if this use of manure did not reduce the need for 
commercial fertilizer. "I don't buy any fertilizer," Mr. Lapp says. (He does 
use an herbicide on his cornfields, but only because the time when corn 
needs cultivation is also the time when he is busiest with tours.) 

The present system of rotation and fertilization has been in use on this 
farm, Mr. Lapp says, "as long as I remember." But he himself, with the 
county agent's help, laid the farm off in three-acre strips to help control 
runoff and erosion. Yet even though soil conservation can to a consider- 
able extent be formalized in set patterns of layout and rotation, there is still 
a need for vigilance and intelligent improvisation. This fall, for instance, 
the barley is coming on too late to provide good winter protection. As a 
remedy, Mr. Lapp says, he will cover the barley fields with strawy manure 
on the first morning the ground is frozen. That will protect the fields 
through the winter without smothering the barley. 

One of the best ways to measure the quality of soil husbandry and the 
richness of soil on a farm is to look at its first-year hayfields. How quickly 
will clover and grass make a sod after the land has been row cropped? How 
healthy and productive is it? The height, density, color, and uniformity of 
the plants all have a tale to tell. Mr. Lapp leads the way up past his garden 
to a four-acre hayfield that is good in all respects. It was sowed in the spring 
to red clover, timothy, and a little alsike for the bees.The barley was taken 
off in July. And then in early October the field was mowed for hay, yield- 
ing 400 bales. Next year, it may reasonably be expected to yield 800-1,000 
bales on the first cutting, and 500-600 on the second. 



TWO KINDS OF HORSEPOWER 

When Elmer Lapp was still just a boy, his father, recognizing a gift in 
him, gave him the colts to work. 
"Made you a little proud?" I say. 
He grins and nods. "I guess it did a little bit." 

Because he is a capable horseman and likes horses, he has never quit 
using them— although he has certain uses for a tractor as well. "I'd rather 



ELMER LAPP'S PLACE 



153 



drive horses than a tractor," he says. "I have them here, they're eating, so 

I might as well use them. I'm doing my work while I'm having pleasure. 
If I didn't enjoy it I wouldn't do it." 

He uses a tractor for what a tractor does best, and horses for what they 
do best, keeping in mind always the scale of his operation. "On a small 
farm," he says, "you don't need expensive equipment." And he seems 
immune to the horsepower intoxication that leads so many small farmers 
to buy larger tractors then they need. He paid $2,000 for a John Deere 60 
twenty years ago, and is still using it. It will pull a three-bottom plow. When 
he needs a tractor for an occasional heavier job, such as silo filling, he hires 
a larger one. He does all his plowing and hay baling with his tractor, and 
uses it to load manure. He uses his horses to spread manure, plant corn, 
clip pasture, rake and haul hay. If he is "not pushed too hard," he uses them 
also in seedbed preparation. He is sure that he gets this work done cheap- 
er with horses than with a tractor-even setting aside the value of their colts. 

He says that rubber-tired equipment is far easier on horses than the 
steel-tired, because the tires absorb much of the shock when working over 
rough ground. And he dislikes wide hitches largely because they too are 
hard on horses. On an eight-foot tandem disk he will hitch two in front 
and three behind-or, if the footing is solid and the going relatively easy, he 
will work as many as four abreast. He says that he sees far too much mis- 
treatment of horses through ignorance and indifference— something he 
resents and tries, so far as he can, to correct. 

The use of the horses, whose feed is grown on the farm, greatly extends 
Mr. Lapp's dependence on solar energy, and greatly reduces his depend- 
ence on increasingly expensive fossil fuel energy. The tractor is used to sup- 
plement the energy already available on the farm. 

In addition to the two varieties of horsepower, the farm makes a small 
use of waterpower.The stream is dammed and the impounded water used 
to turn a small water wheel which, in turn, works a water pump. 

It is another manifestation of this farm's thriftiness. Mr. Lapp looks at 
the escaping water with some regret: "That's all going to waste." 



154 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



A WELL - PLANNEDBARN 



HE LAPPS ARE just completing a small barn that is a good example of 



JL the care and the sense of order that have gone into the making of 
their farm. 

This is a "bank barn" with a drive-in loft, approximately thirty by forty- 
eight feet. The lower story is a feeding area that will accommodate five hun- 
dred guineas in the summer and twelve heifers and perhaps as many young 
horses in the winter. It is divided across the middle by a feed bunk which 
extends out into a lot. 

The upper story will have a corn crib across each end, eight feet wide 
by fourteen deep. The area in the center will be for storage of hay and 
equipment.The cribs are to be ventilated by lattices along the lower part of 
the outside walls. Outside, these lattices will be sheltered by awnings, four 
feet wide on one end, but on the other end ten feet wide to provide yet 
more shelter for equipment. 

All possibilities of site, shape, and use have been considered. 



ONCERNED AS HE is that the usable be put to use, that there be no 



V^> waste, still there is nothing utilitarian or mechanistic about Mr. 
Lapp's farm-or his mind. His aim, it seems, is not that the place should be 
put to the fullest use, but that it should have the most abundant life. The 
best farmers, Sir Albert Howard said, imitate nature, not least in the love 
of variety. Elmer Lapp answers to that definition as fully as any farmer I 
have encountered. Like nature herself, he and his family seem preoccupied 
with the filling of niches. 

Driving into the place, one is aware before anything else that wherever 
flowers can be grown flowers are growing; beds and borders are everywhere. 
The barn swallow nests in the milking barn are not there just by happen- 
stance; little wooden steps have been nailed to the joists to encourage them 
to nest there. Elmer Lapp has defended them against milk inspectors-"If 
those barn swallows go, I'm going somewhere else with my milk"— and against 
the cats, which he pens up during the nesting season, "if they get nasty." 




THE ECOLOGICAL PATTERN 




ELMER LAPP'S PLACE 



155 



Among the wild creatures, he seems especially partial to birds.Wild 
waterfowl make themselves peacefully at home along his pasture stream, 
and he speaks of his failure to attract martins with obvious grief. One can 
justify the existence of birds by "insect control," but one can also like them. 
Elmer Lapp likes them. His one acknowledged regret about his place is that 
it doesn't have a woodlot. He could use the firewood; he would also like the 
wild creatures it would attract. Above his row of beehives is a border of 
sudan grass that he has let go to seed for the birds. 

He likes too the buff Cochin bantams that live in the milking barn and 
the stable— they scatter the manure piles and so keep flies from hatching 
—and the goldfish who live in the drinking trough and keep the water 
clean. Walking around the place, I keep being surprised by some other crea- 
ture that has found room and board there, and is contributing a little some- 
thing-maybe only pleasure-in return: peafowl, wild turkeys, pigeons, a pair 
of bobwhites. 

For a man giftedly practical, Mr. Lapp justifies what he has and does 
remarkably often by his likes. One finally realizes that on the Lapp farm 
one is surrounded by an abounding variety of lives that are there, and are 
thriving there, because Elmer Lapp likes them. And from that it is only a 
step to the realization that the commercial enterprises of the farm are like- 
wise there, and thriving, because he likes them too. The Belgians and the 
Guernseys are profitable, in large part, because they were liked before they 
were profitable. Mr. Lapp is as fine a farmer as he is because liking has 
joined his intelligence intricately to his place. 

And that is why the place makes sense. All the patterns of the farm are 
finally gathered into an ecological pattern; it is one "household," its various 
parts joined to each other and the whole joined to nature, to the world, by 
liking, by delighted and affectionate understanding. The ecological pattern 
is a pattern of pleasure. 



ON THE SOIL AND HEALTH 



(2006) 



IN 1964 MY wife Tanya and I bought a rough and neglected little farm on 
which we intended to grow as much of our own food as we could. My 
editor at the time was Dan Wickenden who was an organic gardener and 
whose father, Leonard Wickenden, had written a practical and in- spiring 
book, Gardening with Nature, which I bought and read. Tanya and I wanted 
to raise our own food because we liked the idea of being independent to 
that extent, and because we did not like the toxicity, expensiveness, and 
wastefulness of "modern" food production. Gardening with 'Nature was writ- 
ten for people like us, and it helped us to see that what we wanted to do 
was possible. I asked Dan where his father's ideas had come from, and he 
gave me the name of Sir Albert Howard. My reading of Howard, which 
began at that time, has never stopped, for I have returned again and again 
to his work and his thought. I have been aware of his influence in virtual- 
ly everything I have done, and I don't expect to graduate from it. That is 
because his way of dealing with the subject of agriculture is also a way of 
dealing with the subject of life in this world. His thought is systematic, 
coherent, and inexhaustible. 

Sir Albert Howard published several books and also many articles in 
journals of agricultural science.The two of his books that are best known 
were addressed both to general readers and to his fellow scientists: An 
Agricultural Testament and The Soil and Health. He was born in 1873 to a 
farming family in Shropshire, and he died in 1947. 

An Agricultural Testament and The Soil and Health are products of 



157 



158 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



Howard's many years as a government scientist in India, during which he 
conceived, and set upon a sound scientific footing, the kind of agriculture 
to which his followers have applied the term "organic." But by 1940, when 
the first of these books was published, the industrialization of agriculture 
had already begun. By 1947, when The Soil and Health was published, 
World War II had proved the effectiveness of the mechanical and chemical 
technology that in the coming decades would radically alter both the prac- 
tice of agriculture and its underlying assumptions. 

This "revolution" marginalized Howard's work and the kind of agricul- 
ture he advocated. So-called organic agriculture survived only on the mar- 
gin. It was practiced by some farmers of admirable independence and good 
sense and also by some authentic nuts. In the hands of the better practi- 
tioners, it was proven to be a healthful, productive, and economical way of 
farming. But while millions of their clients spent themselves into bank- 
ruptcy on industrial supplies, the evangelists of industrial agriculture in 
government and the universities ignored the example of the successful 
organic farmers, just as they ignored the equally successful example of 
Amish farming. 

Meanwhile, Howard's thought, as manifested by the "organic move- 
ment," was seriously oversimplified.As it was understood and prescribed, 
organic agriculture improved the health of crops by building humus in the 
soil, and it abstained from the use of toxic chemicals. There is nothing 
objectionable about this kind of agriculture, so far as it goes, but it does not 
go far enough. It does not conceive of farms in terms of their biological and 
economic structure, because it does not connect farming with its ecological 
and social contexts. Under the current and now official definition of 
organic farming, it is possible to have a huge "organic" farm that grows only 
one or two crops, has no animals or pastures, is entirely dependent on 
industrial technology and economics, and imports all its fertility and ener- 
gy. It was precisely this sort of specialization and oversimplification that Sir 
Albert Howard worked and wrote against all his life. 

At present this movement (if we can still apply that term to an effort 
that is many-branched, multicentered, and always in flux) in at least some 
of its manifestations appears to be working decisively against such oversim- 



ON THE SOIL AND HELTH 



159 



plification and the industrial gigantism that oversimplification allows. 
Some food companies as well as some consumers now understand that 
only the smaller family farms, such as those of the Amish, permit the diver- 
sity and the careful attention that Howard's standards require. 

Howard's fundamental assumption was that the processes of agriculture, 
if they are to endure, have to be analogous to the processes of nature. If one 
is farming in a place previously forested, then the farm must be a systemat- 
ic analogue of the forest, and the farmer must be a student of the forest. 
Howard stated his premise as a little allegory: 

The main characteristic of Nature's farming can ... he summed up in 
a few words. Mother earth never attempts to farm without live stock; 
she always raises mixed crops; great pains are taken to preserve the soil 
and to prevent erosion; the mixed vegetable and animal wastes are con- 
verted into humus; there is no waste; the processes of growth and the 
processes of decay balance one another; ample provision is made to 
maintain large reserves of fertility; the greatest care is taken to store the 
rainfall; both plants and animals are left to protect themselves against 
disease. 1 

Nature is the ultimate value of the practical or economic world. We cannot 
escape either it or our dependence on it. It is, so to speak, its own context, 
whereas the context of agriculture is, first, nature and then the human 
economy. Harmony between agriculture and its natural and human con- 
texts would be health, and health was the invariable standard of Howard's 
work. His aim always was to treat "the whole problem of health in soil, 
plant, animal, and man as one great subject." 2 And Louise Howard spells 
this out in Sir Albert Howard in India: 

A fertile soil, that is, a soil teeming with healthy life in the shape of 
abundant microflora and microfauna, will bear healthy plants, and 
these, when consumed by animals and man, will confer health on ani- 
mals and man. But an infertile soil, that is, one lacking sufficient mi- 
crobial, fungous, and other life, will pass on some form of deficiency to 



160 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



the plant, and such plant, in turn, will pass on some form of deficien- 
cy to animal and man. 3 

This was Howard's "master idea" and he understood that it implied a long- 
term research agenda, calling for "a boldly revised point of view and entire- 
ly fresh investigations." 4 

His premise, then, was that the human economy, which is inescapably 
a land-using economy, must be constructed as an analogue of the organic 
world, which is inescapably its practical context. And so he was fundamen- 
tally at odds with the industrial economy, which sees creatures, including 
humans, as machines, and agriculture, like ultimately the entire human 
economy, as an analogue of an industrial system. This was, and is, the 
inevitable and characteristic product of the dead-end materialism that is 
the premise of both industrialism and the science that supports it. 

Howard understood that such reductionism could not work for agriculture: 

But the growing of crops and the raising of live stock belong to biology, 
a domain where everything is alive and which is poles asunder from 
chemistry and physics. IsAany of the things that matter on the land, 
such as soil fertility, tilth, soil management, the quality of produce, the 
bloom and health of animals, the general management of live stock, 
the working relations between master and man, the esprit de corps of 
the farm as a whole, cannot be weighed or measured. Nevertheless their 
presence is everything: their absence spells failure. 5 

This understanding has a scientific basis, as it should have, for Howard was 
an able and conscientious scientist. But I think it comes also from in- 
tuition, and probably could not have come otherwise. Howard's intuition 
was that of a man who was a farmer by birth and heritage and who was a 
sympathetic as well as a scientific observer of the lives of plants, animals, 
and farmers. 

If the FARM is to last— if it is to be "sustainable," as we now say— then it must 
waste nothing. It must obey in all its processes what Howard called "the law 
of return." Under this law, agriculture produces no waste; what is taken 



ON THE SOIL AND HELTH 



161 



from the soil is returned to it. Growth must be balanced by decay: "In this 
breaking down of organic matter we see in operation the reverse of the 
building-up process which takes place in the leaf." 6 

The balance between growth and decay is the sole principle of stability 
in nature and in agriculture. And this balance is never static, never finally 
achieved, for it is dependent upon a cycle, which in nature, and within the 
limits of nature, is self-sustaining, but which in agriculture must be made 
continuous by purpose and by correct methods. "This cycle," Howard 
wrote, "is constituted of the successive and repeated processes of birth, 
growth, maturity, death, and decay." 7 

The interaction, the interdependence, of life and death, which in 
nature is the source of an inexhaustible fecundity, is the basis of a set of 
analogies, to which agriculture and the rest of the human economy must 
conform in order to endure, and which is ultimately religious, as Howard 
knew: "An eastern religion calls this cycle the Wheel of Life . . . Death 
supersedes life and life rises again from what is dead and decayed." 8 

The maintenance of this cycle is the practical basis of good farming 
and its moral basis as well: 

[T]he correct relation between the processes of growth and the process- 
es of decay is the first principle of successful farming. Agriculture must 
always be balanced. If we speed up growth we must accelerate decay. 
If on the other hand, the soil's reserves are squandered, crop produc- 
tion ceases to be good farming: it becomes something very different. The 
farmer is transformed into a bandit. 9 

IT SEEMS TO me that Howard's originating force, innate in his character 
and refined in his work, was his sense of context.This made him eminent 
and effective in his own day, and it makes his work urgently relevant to 
our own. He lacked completely the specialist impulse, so prominent 
among the scientists and intellectuals of the present-day university, to see 
things in isolation. 

He himself began as a specialist, a mycologist, but he soon saw that this 
made him "a laboratory hermit," and he felt that this was fundamentally 
wrong: 



162 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



I was an investigator of plant diseases, but I had myself no crops on 
which I could try out the remedies I advocated: I could not take my 
own advice before offering it to other people. It was borne in on me that 
there was a wide chasm between science in the laboratory and practice 
in the field, and 1 began to suspect that unless this gap could be bridged 
no real progress could be made in the control of plant diseases: research 
and practice would remain apart: mycological work threatened to 
degenerate into little more than a convenient agency by which— provid- 
ed I issued a sufficient supply of learned reports fortified by a judicious 
mixture of scientific jargon— practical difficulties could be side- 
tracked.' 0 

The theme of his life's work was his effort to bridge this gap. The way to do 
it was simply to refuse to see anything in isolation. Everything, as he saw it, 
existed within a context, outside of which it was unintelligible. Moreover, 
every problem existed within a context, outside of which it was unsolvable. 
Agriculture, thus, cannot be understood or its problems solved without 
respect to context. The same applied even to an individual plant or crop. 
And this respect for context properly set the standard and determined the 
methodology of agricultural science: 

The basis of research was obviously to be investigation directed to the 
whole existence of a selected crop, namely, "the plant itself in relation 
to the soil in which it grows, to the conditions of village agriculture 
under which it is cultivated, and with reference to the economic uses of 
the product"; in other words research was to be integral, never frag- 
mented." 

If nothing exists in isolation, then all problems are circumstantial; no prob- 
lem resides, or can be solved, in anybody's department. A disease was, thus, 
a symptom of a larger disorder. The following passage shows as well as any 
the way his mind worked: 

1 found when 1 took up land in India and learned what the people of 



ON THE SOIL AND HELTH 



163 



the country know, that the diseases of plants and animals were very 
useful agents for keeping me in order, and for teaching me agriculture. 
I have learnt more from the diseases of plants and animals than I have 
from all the professors of Cambridge, Rothamsted and other places who 
gave me my preliminary training. I argued the matter in this way. If 
diseases attacked my crops, it was because 1 was doing something 
wrong. I therefore used diseases to teach me. In this way I really learnt 
agriculture— from my father and from my relatives and from the profes- 
sors I only obtained a mass of preliminary information. Diseases 
taught me to understand agriculture. 1 think if we used diseases more 
instead of running to sprays and killing off pests, and if we let diseases 
rip and then found out what is wrong and then tried to put it right, we 
should get much deeper into agricultural problems than we shall do by 
calling in all these artificial aids. After all, the destruction of a pest is 
the evasion of rather than the solution of, all agricultural problems. 12 

The implied approach to the problem of disease is illustrated by the way 
Howard and his first wife, Gabrielle, dealt with the problem of indigo wilt: 

In fifteen years £54,207 had been spent on research, at that time a 
large sum.Yet the Imperial Entomologist could find no insect, the 
Imperial Mycologist no fungus, and the Imperial Bacteriologist no 
virus to account for the plague. 

The Howards proceeded differently. Their start was to grow the crop on 
a field scale and in the best possible way, taking note of local meth- 
ods.Their observation was directed to the whole plant, above and below 
ground; they followed the crop throughout its life history; they looked 
at all the surrounding circumstances, soil, moisture, temperature. But 
they looked for no virus, no fungus, and no insect." 

And it was the Howards who solved the problem. The plants were wilting, 
they found, primarily because the soils were becoming water-logged during 
the monsoon, killing the roots; the plants were wilting and dying from star- 
vation. It was a problem of management, and it was solved by changes in 
management. But it could not have been solved except by studying the 



164 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



whole plant in its whole context. 

Because he refused to accept the academic fragmentation that had 
become conventional by his time, Howard, of course, was "accused of 
invading fields not his own," 14 and this he had done intentionally and in 
accordance with "the guiding principle of the closest contact between 
research and those to be served." 15 

AGRICULTURE IS practiced inescapably in a context, and its context must 
not be specialized or simplified. Its context, first of all, is the nature of the 
place in which it is practiced, but it is also the society and the economy of 
those who practice it. And just as there are penalties for ignoring the natu- 
ral context, so there are penalties for ignoring the human one. As Howard 
saw it, the agricultural industrialists' apparent belief that food production 
could be harmlessly divorced from the economic interest of farmers need- 
lessly repeats a historical failure: 

Judged by the ordinary standards of achievement the agricultural his- 
tory of the Roman Empire ended in failure due to inability to realize 
the fundamental principle that the maintenance of soil fertility cou- 
pled with the legitimate claims of the agricultural population should 
never have been allowed to come in conflict with the operations of the 
capitalist.The most important possession of a country is its population. 
If this is maintained in health and vigour everything else will follow; 
if this is allowed to decline nothing, not even great riches, can save the 
country from eventual ruin. 16 

The obligation of a country's agriculture, then, is to maintain its people in 
health, and this applies equally to the people who eat and to the people 
who produce the food. 

Howard accepted this obligation unconditionally as the obligation also 
of his own work. He realized, moreover, that this obligation imposed strict 
limits both upon the work of farmers and upon his work as a scientist: 
First, neither farming nor experimentation should usurp the tolerances or 
violate the nature of the place where the work is done; and second, the 
work must respect and preserve the livelihoods of the local community. 



ON THE SOIL AND HELTH 



165 



Before going to work, agricultural scientists are obliged to know both the 
place where their work is to be done and the people for whom they are 
working. It is remarkable that Howard came quietly, by thought and work, 
to these realizations a half century and more before they were forced upon 
us by the ecological and economic failures of industrial agriculture. 

In India he used his training as a scientist and his ability to observe and 
think for himself, just as he would have been expected to do. But he also 
learned from the peasant farmers of the country, whom he respected as his 
"professors." He valued them for their knowledge of the land, for their 
industry, and for their "accuracy of eye." 17 He accepted also the economic 
and technological circumstances of those farmers as the limit within which 
he himself should do his work. He saw that it would be possible to ruin his 
clients by thoughtless or careless innovation: 

Often improvements are possible but they are not economic. ... In 
India the cultivators are mostly in debt and the holdings are small. Any 
capital required for developments has to be borrowed. A large number 
of possible improvements are barred by the fact that the extra return is 
not large enough to pay the high interest on the capital involved and 
also to yield a profit to the cultivator. 18 

The reader may wish to contrast this way of thinking with that of the Green 
Revolution or with that of the headlong industrialization of American agri- 
culture sinceWorldWar II, in both of which the only recognized limit was 
technological, and in neither of which was there any concern for the abili- 
ty of farmers or their communities to bear the costs. 
Howard's solution to the problem was simply to do his work within the 
technological limits of the local farmers: 

The existing system could not be radically changed, but it might be 
de- veloped in useful ways.This must never exceed what the cultiva- 
tor could afford, and, in a way, also what he was used to. This prin- 
ciple Sir Albert kept in mind to the very end . . . his standard seems 
to have been the possession of a yoke of oxen; when more power was 
needed, the presumption was that the second yoke could be borrowed 



166 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



from a neighbor. Thus the maximum draught contemplated was four 
animals. 19 

By the observance of such limits, Howard was enfolded consciously and 
conscientiously within the natural and human communities that he 
endeavored to serve. 

No UNIVERSITY THAT I have heard of, land-grant or other, has yet attempt- 
ed to establish its curriculum and its intellectual structure on Sir Albert 
Howard's "one great subject," or on his determination to serve respectfully 
and humbly the local population. But a university most certainly could do 
so, and in doing so it could bring to bear all its disciplines and depart- 
ments. In doing so, that is to say, it could become in truth a university. 

At present our universities are not simply growing and expanding, 
according to the principle of "growth" universal in industrial societies, but 
they are at the same time disintegrating. They are a hodge-podge of unre- 
lated parts. There is no unifying aim and no common critical standard that 
can serve equally well all the diverse parts or departments. 

The fashion now is to think of universities as industries or businesses. 
University presidents, evidently thinking of themselves as CEOs, talk of 
"business plans" and "return on investment," as if the industrial economy 
could provide an aim and a critical standard appropriate either to educa- 
tion or to research. 

But this is not possible. No economy, industrial or otherwise, can sup- 
ply an appropriate aim or standard. Any economy must be either true or 
false to the world and to our life in it. If it is to be true, then it must be 
made true, according to a standard that is not economic. 

To regard the economy as an end or as the measure of success is mere- 
ly to reduce students, teachers, researchers, and all they know or learn to 
merchandise. It reduces knowledge to "property" and education to training 
for the "job market." 

If, on the contrary, Howard was right in his belief that health is the 
"one great subject," then a unifying aim and a common critical standard are 
clearly implied. Health is at once quantitative and qualitative; it requires 



ON THE SOIL AND HELTH 



167 



both sufficiency and goodness. It is comprehensive (it is synonymous with 
"wholeness"), for it must leave nothing out. And it is uncompromisingly 
local and particular; it has to do with the sustenance of particular places, 
creatures, human bodies, and human minds. 

If a university began to assume responsibility for the health of its place 
and its local constituents, then all of its departments would have a com- 
mon aim, and they would have to judge their place and themselves and one 
another by a common standard. They would need one another's knowl- 
edge. They would have to communicate with one another; the diversity of 
specialists would have to speak to one another in a common language. And 
here again Howard is exemplary, for he wrote, and presumably spoke, a 
plain, vigorous, forthright English-no jargon, no condescension, no osten- 
tation, no fooling around. 

Notes 

1. An Agricultural Testament (London: Oxford University Press, 1956), 4. 

2. Sir Albert Howard, The Soil and Health (Lexington: University Press of Kentucky, 2006), 
11. 

3. Louise E. Howard, Sir Albert Howard in India (Emmaus, Pa.: Rodale Press, 1954), 162. 

4. The Soil and Health, 11. 

5. An Agricultural Testament, 196. 

6. The Soil and Health, 22. 

7. Ibid., 18. 

8. Ibid. 

9. An Agricultural Testament, 25. 

10. The Soil and Health, 1-2. 

11. Sir Albert Howard in India, 42. 

12. Howard, as quoted in Sir Albert Howard in India, 190. 

13. Sir Albert Howard in India, 170. 

14. Ibid., 42. 

15. Ibid., 44. 



168 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 

16. An Agricultural Testament, 9. 

17. Sir Albert Howard in India, 222 and 228. 

18. Howard, as quoted in Sir Albert Howard in India, 37-38. 

19. Sir Albert Howard in India, 224. 



Agriculture from the Roots Up 



(2004) 



HENRY David Thoreau wrote somewhere that hundreds are hacking 
at the branches for every one who is striking at the root. He meant 
this as a metaphor, but it applies literally to modern agriculture and to the 
science of modern agriculture. As it has become more and more industri- 
alized, agriculture increasingly has been understood as an enterprise estab- 
lished upon the surface of the ground. Most people nowadays lack even a 
superficial knowledge of agriculture, and most who do know something 
about it are paying little or no attention to what is happening under the 
surface. 

The scientists at The Land Institute in Salina, Kansas, on the con- 
trary, are striking at the root. Their study of the root and the roots of our 
agricultural problems has produced a radical criticism, leading to a pro- 
posed solution that is radical. 

Their CRITICISM is made radical by one crucial choice: the adoption of the 
natural ecosystem as the first standard of agricultural performance, having 
priority over the standard of productivity and certainly over the delusional 
and dangerous industrial standard of "efficiency." That single change makes 
a momentous difference, one that is historical and cultural as well as scien- 
tific. 

By the standard of the natural or the healthy ecosystem, we see as if 
suddenly the shortcomings, not only of industrial agriculture but of agri- 
culture itself, insofar as agriculture has consisted of annual monocultures. 



169 



170 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



To those of us who are devoted to agriculture in any of its historical forms, 
such criticism is inevitably painful. And yet we may see its justice and ac- 
cept it, understanding how much is at stake. To others, who have founded 
their careers or their businesses precisely upon the shortcomings of agri- 
culture as we now have it, this criticism will perhaps be even more painful, 
and no doubt they will resist with all the great power we know they have. 

Even so, this is a criticism for which the time is ripe. A rational denial 
of its justice is no longer possible. There are many reasons for this, but the 
main one, I think, is the virtual meltdown of the old boundaries of special- 
ist thought in agriculture-a meltdown that I hope foretells the same fate 
for the boundaries of all specialist thought. 

The justifying assumptions of the industrial agriculture that we now 
have are based on a reductive science working within strictly bounded spe- 
cializations. This agriculture, an agglomeration of specialties, appeared per- 
fectly rational and salutary so long as it was assumable that efficiency and 
productivity were adequate standards, that husbandry was safely reducible 
to science and fertility to chemistry, that organisms are merely machines, 
that agriculture is under no obligation to nature, that it has only agricultur- 
al results, and that it can be confidently based upon "cheap" fossil fuels. 

The inventors of this agriculture assumed, in short, that the human 
will is sovereign in the universe, that the only laws are the laws of mechan- 
ics, and that the material world and its "natural resources" are without 
limit.These are the assumptions that, acknowledged or not, underlie the 
"war" by which we humans have undertaken to "conquer" nature, and 
which is the dominant myth of modern intellectual life. 

In THE DAYS of human darkness and ignorance, now supposedly past, 
we found ways to acknowledge the sanctity of nature and to honor her as 
the common mother of all creatures, including ourselves.We conducted 
our relations with her by prayer, propitiation, skilled work, thrift, caution, 
and care. Our concern about that relationship produced the concepts of 
usufruct and stewardship. A few lines from the "Two Cantos of Mutabilitie" 
that Edmund Spenser placed at the end of The Faerie Queene will suffice to 
give a sense of our ancient veneration: 



AGRICULTURE FROM THE ROOTS US 



171 



Then forth issewed (great goddesse) great dame 'Nature, 
With goodly port and gracious Majesty; 
Being far greater and more tall of stature 
Than any of the gods or Powers on hie . . . 

This great Grandmother of all creatures bred 

Great Nature, ever young yet full of eld, Still moving, yet unmoved 
from her sted; Unseen of any, yet of all beheld . . . 

Thus, though he was a Christian, Spenser still saw fit at the end of the six- 
teenth century to present Nature as the genius of the sublunary world, a 
figure of the greatest majesty, mystery, and power, the source of all earthly 
life. He addressed her, in addition, as the supreme judge of all her crea- 
tures, ruling by standards that we would now call ecological: 

Who Right to all dost deal indifferently, 
Damning all Wrong and tortious Injurie, 
Which any of thy creatures do to other 
(Oppressing them with power, unequally) 
Sith of them all thou art the equall mother, 
And knittest each to each, as brother unto brother. 

And then, at about Spenser's time or a little after, we set forth in our "war 
against nature" with the purpose of conquering her and wringing her pow- 
erful and lucrative secrets from her by various forms of "tortious Injurie." 
This we have thought of as our "enlightenment" and as "progress." But in 
the event this war, like most wars, has turned out to be a trickier business 
than we expected. We must now face two shocking surprises. The first sur- 
prise is that if we say and believe that we are at war with nature, then we 
are in the fullest sense at warThat is, we are both opposing and being 
opposed, and the costs to both sides are extremely high. 

The second surprise is that we are not winning. On the evidence now 
available, we have to conclude that we are losing— and, moreover, that 
there was never a chance that we could win. Despite the immense power 



172 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



and violence that we have deployed against her, nature is handing us one 
defeat after another. Even in our most grievous offenses against her-as in 
the present epidemic of habitat destruction and species extinction-we are 
being defeated, for in the long run we can less afford the losses than 
nature can. And we have to look upon soil erosion and the spread of exot- 
ic diseases, weeds, and pests as nature's direct reprisals for our violations 
of her laws. Sometimes she seems terrifyingly serene in her triumphs over 
us, as when, simply by refusing to absorb our pollutants, she forces us to 
live in our mess. 

Thus she has forced us to recognize that the context of American agri- 
culture is not merely fields and farms or the free market or the economy, 
but it is also the polluted Mississippi River, the hypoxic zone in the Gulf of 
Mexico, all the small towns whose drinking water contains pesticides and 
nitrates, the pumped-down aquifers and the no-longer-flowing rivers, and 
all the lands that we have scalped, gouged, poisoned, or destroyed utterly 
for "cheap" fuels and raw materials. 

Thus she is forcing us to believe what the great teachers and prophets 
have always told us and what the ecologists are telling us again: All things 
are connected; the context of everything is everything else. By now, many 
of us know, and more are learning, that if you want to evaluate the agricul- 
ture of a region, you must begin not with a balance sheet, but with the 
local water. How continuously do the small streams flow? How clear is the 
water? How much sediment and how many pollutants are carried in the 
runoff? Are the ponds and creeks and rivers fit for swimming? Can you eat 
the fish? 

We know, or we are learning, that from the questions about water we 
go naturally to questions about the soil. Is it staying in place? What is its 
water-holding capacity? Does it drain well? How much humus is in it? What 
of its biological health? How often and for how long is it exposed to the 
weather? How deep in it do the roots go? 

Such are THE questions that trouble and urge and inspire the scientists at 
The Land Institute, for everything depends upon the answers. The an- 
swers, as these scientists know, will reveal not only the state of the health 
of the landscape, but also the state of the culture of the people who in- 



AGRICULTURE FROM THE ROOTS US 



173 



habit and use the landscape. Is it a culture of respect, thrift, and seemly 
skills, or a culture of indifference and mechanical force? A culture of life, 
or a culture of death? 

And beyond those questions are questions insistently practical and eco- 
nomic, questions of accounting. What is the worth, to us humans with our 
now insupportable health care industry, of ecological health? Is our health 
in any way separable from the health of our economic landscapes? Must not 
the health of water and soil be accounted an economic asset? Will not this 
greater health support, sustain, and in the long run cheapen the productiv- 
ity of our farms? 

If our war against nature destroys the health of water and soil, and thus 
inevitably the health of agriculture and our own health, and can only lead 
to our economic ruin, then we need to try another possibility. And there is 
only one: If we cannot establish an enduring or even a humanly bearable 
economy by our attempt to defeat nature, then we will have to try living in 
harmony and cooperation with her. 

By its adoption of the healthy ecosystem as the appropriate standard of 
agricultural performance,The Land Institute has rejected competition as 
the fundamental principle of economics, and therefore of the applied sci- 
ences, and has replaced it with the principle of harmony. In doing so, it has 
placed its work within a lineage and tradition that predate both industrial- 
ism and modern science. The theme of a human and even an economic 
harmony with nature goes back many hundreds of years in the literary 
record. Its age in the prehistoric cultures can only be conjectured, but we 
may confidently assume that it is ancient, probably as old as the human 
race. In the early twentieth century this theme was applied explicitly to agri- 
culture by writers such as F. H. King, Liberty Hyde Bailey, J. Russell Smith, 
Sir Albert Howard, and Aldo Leopold, Howard being the one who gave it 
the soundest and most elaborate scientific underpinning.This modern lin- 
eage was interrupted by the juggernaut of industrial agriculture following 
World War II. But, in the 1970s, when Wes Jackson began thinking about 
the Kansas prairie as a standard and model for Kansas farming, he took up 
the old theme at about where Howard had left it, doing so remarkably with- 
out previous knowledge of Howard. 



174 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



And so, in espousing the principle and the goal of harmony, The Land 
Institute acquired an old and honorable ancestry. It acquired at the same 
time, in the same way, a working principle also old and honorable: that of 
art as imitation of nature. The initiating question was this: If, so to speak, 
you place a Kansas wheatfield beside a surviving patch of the native Kansas 
prairie, what is the difference? 

Well, the primary difference, obvious to any observer, is that, whereas 
the wheatfield is a monoculture of annuals, the plant community of the 
prairie is highly diverse and perennial. There are many implications in that 
difference, not all of which are agricultural, but five of which are of imme- 
diate and urgent agricultural interest: The prairie's loss of soil to erosion is 
minimal; it is highly efficient in its ability to absorb, store, and use water; 
it makes the maximum use of every year's sunlight; it builds and preserves 
its own fertility; and it protects itself against pests and diseases. 

The next question, the practical one, follows logically and naturally 
from the first: How might we contrive, let us say, a Kansas farm in imita- 
tion of a Kansas prairie, acquiring for agriculture the several ecological serv- 
ices of the prairie along with the economic benefit of a sufficient harvest 
of edible seeds? And so we come to the great project of The Land Institute. 

I lack the technical proficiency to comment at much length on this 
work. I would like to end simply by saying how I believe the science now 
in practice at The Land Institute differs from the science of industrial 
agriculture. 

WE ARE LIVING in an age of technological innovation. Our preoccupation 
with invention and novelty has begun, by this late day, to look rather 
absurd, specially in our strict avoidance of cost accounting. What inven- 
tion, after all, has done more net good or given more net pleasure than 
soap? And who invented soap? It is all too easy, under the circumstances, 
to imagine a media publicist snatching at The Land Institute's project as 
"innovation on an epic scale" or "the next revolution in agriculture" or "the 
new scientific frontier." 

But these scientists are contemplating no such thing. Their vision and 
their work do not arise from or lead to any mechanical or chemical break- 



AGRICULTURE FROM THE ROOTS US 



175 



through; they do not depend on any newly discovered fuel. The innovation 
they have in mind is something old under the sun: a better adaptation of 
the human organism to its natural habitat. They are not seeking to imple- 
ment a technological revolution or a revolution of any kind. They are inter- 
ested merely in improving our fundamental relationship to the earth, 
changing the kind of roots we put down and deepening the depth we put 
them down to. This is not revolutionary, because it is merely a part of a 
long job that we have not finished, that we have tried for a little while to 
finish in the wrong way, but one that we will never finish if we do it the 
right way. Harmony between our human economy and the natural 
world— local adaptation— is a perfection we will never finally achieve but 
must continuously try for. There is never a finality to it because it involves 
living creatures who change. The soil has living creatures in it. It has live 
roots in it, perennial roots if it is lucky. If it is the soil of the right kind of 
farm, it has a farm family growing out of it. The work of adaptation must 
go on because the world changes; our places change and we change; we 
change our places and our places change us. The science of adaptation, 
then, is unending. Anybody who undertakes to adapt agriculture to a 
place-or, in J. Russell Smith's words, to fit the farming to the farm-will 
never run out of problems or want for intellectual stimulation. 

The science of The Land Institute promptly exposes the weakness of 
the annual thought of agricultural industrialism because it measures its 
work by the standard of the natural ecosystem, which gives pride of place 
to perennials. It exposes also the weakness of the top-down thought of tech- 
nological innovation by proceeding from the roots up, and by aiming not 
at universality and uniformity, but at local adaptation. It would deepen the 
formal limits of agricultural practice many feet below the roots of the annu- 
al grain crops, but it would draw in the limits of concern to the local water- 
shed, ecosystem, farm, and field. This is by definition a science of place, 
operating within a world of acknowledged limits-of space, time, energy, 
soil, water, and human intelligence. It is a science facing, in the most local 
and intimate terms, a world of daunting formal complexity and of an ulti- 
mately impenetrable mystery-exactly the world that the reductive sciences 
of industrial agriculture have sought to oversimplify and thus ignore. This 
new science, in its ancient quest, demands the acceptance of human igno- 



176 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 

ranee as the ever-present starting point of human work, and it requires the 
use of all the intelligence we have. 



PART III 
FOOD 



author's note 



PART III CALLS for a few words of explanation. The publisher's idea was 
to show in this gathering of writings the connections that make one 
subject of farming, farms, farmers, and food. I agreed, thinking the idea 
was a good one. But if we limited the contents of our book to essays, as at 
first we thought we would do, we were going to come up short on 
food.Though I have written many essays on farming, farms, and farmers, I 
have written only one specifically on food. I am by no means a chef, and as 
a cook I am limited to frying and scorching. 

And so we decided to include in Part III, in addition to the lone essay, 
"The Pleasures of Eating," a selection from my fiction of passages in which 
people eat. This is a good idea also, I think, because it unspecializes the 
idea of food. All the episodes from my stories and novels are not about 
food only, but about meals. You can eat food by yourself. A meal, according 
to my understanding anyhow, is a communal event, bringing together fam- 
ily members, neighbors, even strangers. At its most ordinary, it involves 
hospitality, giving, receiving, and gratitude. It pleases me that in these fic- 
tional passages food is placed in its circumstances of history, work, and 
companionship. 

I have provided notes to accompany these episodes, to say when they 
took place, and to give some sense of the stories they belong to. 

But I need to say, furthermore, something about the part of the 
women in these episodes. The effort of justice to women, in addition to 
the substantial good it has done and is doing, has attached a sense of 
belittlement to "women's work." I know that there are reasons for this. But 



179 



180 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



understandable as it may be, it is unjust when it extends to traditional 
farm housewifery. 

People and their domestic arrangements are imperfect, of course. 
Abuses no doubt can be found in the customs and usages of any time, no 
matter how enlightened or liberated. But the women in the episodes that 
follow, as I think is obvious, are not the "little women" of the liberationist 
stereotype, and are related distantly if at all to the housewives of the mod- 
ern suburbs. They are not consumers. They are not openers of cans or 
heaters of frozen dinners or stirrers of "mixes." 

On the contrary, they are, with their menfolk, managers of domestic 
economies that are complex, practically and culturally. These economies 
unite household and farm. They are as dependent on old knowledge and 
immediate intelligence as on the land. In accordance with tradition, these 
women do the cooking, but this is a cooking that is only a part of an intri- 
cate seasonal procedure that includes the cultivation of plants and the nur- 
turing of animals, harvesting and bringing in, slaughtering and butchering, 
preserving and canning and storing for the winter. How all this work was 
(and sometimes still is) divided between the sexes would vary, according to 
preferences and abilities, from one household and marriage to another. 
But both men and women participated and were associated in the work. 

Justice to these women requires recognition of the entirely admirable 
knowledge, intelligence, and skill that they applied to their "women's 
work." Moreover, many of these women were perfectly capable also of 
"men's work." The reader will notice, in the passage from The Memory of Old 
Jack, that Mary Penn is helping to prepare a harvest dinner, but also that 
she is wearing work clothes. After the women have eaten (with the men fed 
and gone, this will be a leisurely, quietly sociable meal that the women 
have) and after they have washed the dishes and set the kitchen to rights, 
Mary will go to the field to work with the men. Hannah would be going 
too if she were not pregnant. 



from That Distant Land 



Here is a glimpse of an old way of family life and hospitality before the twentieth 
century, and its invariable resort to war and industrial destruction, changed every- 
thing.These paragraphs are from the short story "Turn Back the Bed." 

LD Ant'ny was a provider, and he did provide. He saw to it that 



V ' twelve hogs were slaughtered for his own use every fall— and twenty- 
four hams and twenty-four shoulders and twenty-four middlings were hung 
in his smokehouse. And his wife, Maw Proudfoot, kept a flock of turkeys 
and a flock of geese and a flock of guineas, and her henhouse was as pop- 
ulous as a county seat. And long after he was "too old to farm," Old Ant'ny 
grew a garden as big as some people's crop. He picked and dug and fetched, 
and Maw Proudfoot canned and preserved and pickled and cured as if they 
had an army to feed— which they more or less did, for there were not only 
the announced family gatherings but always somebody or some few hap- 
pening by, and always somebody to give something to. 

The Proudfoot family gatherings were famous. As feasts, as collections 
and concentrations of good things, they were unequaled. Especially in sum- 
mer there was nothing like them, for then there would be old ham and 
fried chicken and gravy, and two or three kinds of fish, and hot biscuits and 
three kinds of cornbread, and potatoes and beans and roasting ears and 
carrots and beets and onions, and corn pudding and corn creamed and 
fried, and cabbage boiled and scalloped, and tomatoes stewed and sliced, 
and fresh cucumbers soaked in vinegar, and three or four kinds of pickles, 
and if it was late enough in the summer there would be watermelons and 




181 



182 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



muskmelons, and there would be pies and cakes and cobblers and 
dumplings, and milk and coffee by the gallon. And there would be, too, 
half a dozen or so gallon or half-gallon stone jugs making their way from 
one adult male to another as surreptitious as moles. For in those days the 
Proudfoot homeplace, with its broad cornfields in the creek bottom, was 
famous also for the excellence of its whiskey. 

So of course these affairs were numerously attended. When the word 
went out to family and in-laws it was bound to be overheard, and people 
came in whose veins Proudfoot blood ran extremely thin, if at all. And 
there would be babble and uproar all day, for every door stood open, and 
the old house was not ceiled; the upstairs floorboards were simply nailed 
to the naked joists, leaving cracks that you could not only hear through 
but in places see through. Whatever happened anywhere could be heard 
everywhere. 

The storm of feet and voices would continue unabated from not long 
after sunup until after sundown when the voice of Old Ant'ny would rise 
abruptly over the multitude: "Well, Maw, turn back the bed. These folks 
want to be gettin' on home." And then, as if at the bidding of some 
Heavenly sign, the family sorted itself into its branches. Children and shoes 
and hats were found, identified, and claimed; horses were hitched; and the 
tribes of the children of Old Ant'ny Proudfoot set out in their various direc- 
tions in the twilight. 



FROM THAT DISTANT LAND 



183 



The following passage also is from a short story, "The Solemn Boy." Going home at 
noon with a load of corn on a bitter cold day between Thanksgiving and Christmas, 
1934, Tol Proudfoot gives a ride to a man and his young son. These are people clear- 
ly displaced by the Depression. Because he understands this, and has seen how poor- 
ly dressed they are for the weather and how cold, and because kindness is anyhow 
his rule,Tol insists that the two strangers come to his house for dinner-the big meal, 
that is to say, that the country people ate at noon. He sends them to the house while 
he drives on to the barn to care for his horses. 

TOL SPOKE TO his team and drove on into the barn lot. He positioned 
the wagon in front of the corncrib, so he could scoop the load off 
after dinner, and then he unhitched the horses. He watered them, led 
them to their stalls, and fed them. 
"Eat, boys, eat," he said. 

And then he started to the house. As he walked along he opened his 
hand, and the old dog put his head under it. 

The MAN and boy evidently had done as he had told them, for they were 
not in sight.Tol already knew how Miss Minnie would have greeted them. 

"Well, come on in!" she would have said, opening the door and seeing 
the little boy. "Looks like we're having company for dinner! Come in here, 
honey, and get warm!" 

He knew how the sight of that little shivering boy would have called 
the heart right out of her. Tol and Miss Minnie had married late, and time 
had gone by, and no child of their own had come. Now they were stricken 
in age, and it had long ceased to be with Miss Minnie after the manner of 
women. 

He told the old dog to lie down on the porch, opened the kitchen 
door, and stepped inside. The room was warm, well lit from the two big 
windows in the opposite wall, and filled with the smells of things cooking. 
They had killed hogs only a week or so before, and the kitchen was full of 
the smell of frying sausage. Tol could hear it sizzling in the skillet. He stood 
just inside the door, unbuttoning his coat and looking around. The boy 
was sitting close to the stove, a little sleepy looking now in the warmth, 



184 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



some color coming into his face.The man was standing near the boy, look- 
ing out the window-feeling himself a stranger, poor fellow, and trying to 
pretend he was somewhere else. 

Tol took off his outdoor clothes and hung them up. He nodded to 
Miss Minnie, who gave him a smile. She was rolling out the dough for an 
extra pan of biscuits. Aside from that, the preparations looked about as 
usual. Miss Minnie ordinarily cooked enough at dinner so that there would 
be leftovers to warm up or eat cold for supper. There would be plenty. The 
presence of the two strangers made Tol newly aware of the abundance, fra- 
grance, and warmth of that kitchen. 

"Cold out," Miss Minnie said. "This boy was nearly frozen." 

Tol saw that she had had no luck either in learning who their guests 
were. "Yes," he said. "Pretty cold." 

He turned to the little washstand beside the door, dipped water from 
the bucket into the wash pan, warmed it with water from the tea-kettle on 
the stove. He washed his hands, splashed his face, groped for the towel. 

As soon as Tol quit looking at his guests, they began to look at him. 
Only now that they saw him standing up could they have seen how big he 
was. He was broad and wide and tall. All his movements had about them 
an air of casualness or indifference as if he were not conscious of his whole 
strength. He wore his clothes with the same carelessness, evidently not hav- 
ing thought of them since he put them on. And though the little boy had 
not smiled, at least not where Tol or Miss Minnie could see him, he must 
at least have wanted to smile at the way Tol's stiff gray hair stuck out hith- 
er and yon after Tol combed it, as indifferent to the comb as if the comb 
had been merely fingers or a stick. But when Tol turned away from the 
washstand, the man looked back to the window and the boy looked down 
at his knee. 

"It's ready," Miss Minnie said to Tol, as she took a pan of biscuits from 
the oven and slid another in. 

Tol went to the chair at the end of the table farthest from the stove. He 
gestured to the two chairs on either side of the table. "Make yourself at 
home, now," he said to the man and the boy. "Sit down, sit down." 

He sat down himself and the two guests sat down. "We're mightily 



FROM THAT DISTANT LAND 



185 



obliged," the man said. 

"Don't wait on me," Miss Minnie said. "I'll be there in just a minute." 

"My boy, reach for that sausage," Tol said. "Take two and pass 'em. 
"Have biscuits," he said to the man. "Naw, that ain't enough.Take two or 
three. There's plenty of 'em." 

There was plenty of everything: a platter of sausage, and more already 
in the skillet on the stove; biscuits brown and light, and more in the oven; 
a big bowl of navy beans, and more in the kettle on the stove, a big bowl of 
applesauce and one of mashed potatoes. There was a pitcher of milk and 
one of buttermilk. 

Tol heaped his plate, and saw to it that his guests heaped theirs. "Eat 
till it's gone," he said, "and don't ask for nothing you don't see." 

Miss Minnie sat down presently, and they all ate. Now and again Tol 
and Miss Minnie glanced at each other, each wanting to be sure the other 
saw how their guests applied themselves to the food. For the man and the 
boy ate hungrily without looking up, as though to avoid acknowledging 
that others saw how hungry they were. And Tol thought, "No breakfast." In 
his concern for the little boy, he forgot his curiosity about where the two 
had come from and where they were going. 

Miss Minnie helped the boy to more sausage and more beans, and she 
buttered two more biscuits and put them on his plate. Tol saw how her 
hand hovered above the boy's shoulder, wanting to touch him. He was a 
nice-looking little boy, but he never smiled. Tol passed the boy the potatoes 
and refilled his glass with milk. 

"Why, he eats so much it makes him poor to carry it," Tol said. "That 
boy can put it away!" 

The boy looked up, but he did not smile or say anything. Neither Tol 
nor Miss Minnie had heard one peep out of him.Tol passed everything to 
the man, who helped himself and did not look up. 

"We surely are obliged," he said. 

Tol said, "Why, I wish you would look. Every time that boy's elbow 
bends, his mouth flies open." 

But the boy did not smile. He was a solemn boy, far too solemn for his age. 
"Well, we know somebody else whose mouth's connected to his elbow, 



186 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



don't we?" Miss Minnie said to the boy, who did not look up and did not 
smile. "Honey, don't you want another biscuit?" 

The men appeared to be finishing up now. She rose and brought to the 
table a pitcher of sorghum molasses, and she brought the second pan of bis- 
cuits, hot from the oven. 

The two men buttered biscuits, and then, when the butter had melted, 
laid them open on their plates and covered them with molasses. And Miss 
Minnie did the same for the boy. She longed to see him smile, and so did 
Tol. 

"Now, Miss Minnie," Tol said, "that boy will want to go easy on them 
biscuits from here on, for we ain't got but three or four hundred of 'em 
left." 

But the boy only ate his biscuits and molasses and did not look at any- 
body. 

And now the meal was ending, and what were they going to do? Tol 
and Miss Minnie yearned toward that nice, skinny, really pretty little boy, 
and the old kitchen filled with their yearning, and maybe there was to be 
no answer. Maybe that man and this little boy would just get up in their 
silence and say, "Much obliged," and go away, and leave nothing of them- 
selves at all. 

"My boy," Tol said-he had his glass half-full of buttermilk in his hand, 
and was holding it up. "My boy, when you drink buttermilk, always 
remember to drink from the near side of the glass-like this." Tol tilted his 
glass and took a sip from the near side. "For drinking from the far side, as 
you'll find out, don't work anything like so well." And then— and perhaps 
to his own surprise— he applied the far side of the glass to his lips, turned 
it up, and poured the rest of the buttermilk right down the front of his 
shirt. And then he looked at Miss Minnie with an expression of absolute 
astonishment. 

For several seconds nobody made a sound. They all were looking at 
Tol, and Tol, with his hair asserting itself in all directions and buttermilk 
on his chin and his shirt and alarm and wonder in his eyes, was looking at 
Miss Minnie. 

And then Miss Minnie said quietly, "Mr. Proudfoot, you are the limit." 



FROM THAT DISTANT LAND 



187 



And then they heard the boy. At first it sounded like he had an ob- 
struction in his throat that he worked at with a sort of strangling. And then 
he laughed. 

He laughed with a free, strong laugh that seemed to open his throat as 
wide as a stovepipe. It was the laugh of a boy who was completely tickled. 
It transformed everything. Miss Minnie smiled. And then Tol laughed his 
big hollering laugh. And then Miss Minnie laughed. And then the boy's 
father laughed.The man and the boy looked up, they all looked full into 
one another's eyes, and they laughed. 

They laughed until Miss Minnie had to wipe her eyes with the hem of 
her apron. 

"Lord," she said, getting up, "what's next?" She went to get Tol a clean 
shirt. 

"Let's have some more biscuits," Tol said. And they all buttered more 
biscuits and passed the molasses again. 



from Hannah Coulter 



Christmas 1941, the Christmas after Pearl Harbor, came not long after Hannah, 
who is speaking here, married Virgil Feltner. Soon after that Christmas Virgil will 
be drafted into the Army, as they have expected. Because the war has so un- settled 
the future, Hannah and Virgil are living with his parents, Margaret and Mat 
Feltner. 

IT WAS THE Christmas season, and we made the most of it. Virgil and I 
cut a cedar tree that filled a corner of the parlor, reached to the ceiling, 
and gave its fragrance to the whole room. We hung its branches with orna- 
ments and lights, and wrapped our presents and put them underneath. 
One evening Virgil called up the Catlett children, pretending to be Santa 
Claus, and wound them up so that Bess and Wheeler nearly never got 
them to bed. We cooked for a week-Nettie Banion, the Feltners' cook, and 
Mrs. Feltner and I. We made cookies and candy, some for ourselves, some 
to give away. We made a fruit cake, a pecan cake, and a jam cake. Mr. 
Feltner went to the smokehouse and brought in an old ham, which we 
boiled and then baked.We made criss-crosses in the fat on top, finished it 
off with a glaze, and then put one clove exactly in the center of each square. 
We talked no end, of course, and joked and laughed. And I couldn't help 
going often to the pantry to look at what we had done and admire it, for 
these Christmas doings ran far ahead of any I had known before. 

Each of us knew that the others were dealing nearly all the time with 
the thought of the war, but that thought we kept in the secret quiet of our 
own minds. Maybe we were thinking too of the sky opening over the shep- 



189 



190 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



herds who were abiding in the field, keeping watch over their flocks, and 
the light of Heaven falling over them, and the angel announcing peace. I 
was thinking of that, and also of the sufferers in the Bethlehem stable, as I 
never had before. There was an ache that from time to time seemed to fall 
entirely through me like a misting rain. The war was a bodily presence. It 
was in all of us, and nobody said a word. 

Virgil and I brought Grandmam over from Shagbark on Christmas 
Eve. She was wearing her Sunday black and her silver earrings and broach. 
To keep from embarrassing me, as I understood, she had bought a nice win- 
ter coat and a little suitcase. She had presents for the Feltners and for Virgil 
and me in a shopping bag that she refused to let Virgil carry. I had worried 
that she would feel out of place at the Feltners, but I need not have. Mr. 
and Mrs. Feltner were at the door to welcome her, and she thanked them 
with honest pleasure and with grace. 

On Christmas morning Nettie Banion's mother-in-law, Aunt Fanny, 
came up to the house with Nettie to resume for the day her old command 
of the kitchen. Joe Banion soon followed them under Aunt Fanny's orders 
to be on hand if needed. 

And then the others came. Bess and Wheeler were first. Their boys flew 
through the front door, leaving it open, waving two new pearl-handled cap 
pistols apiece, followed by their little sisters with their Christmas dolls, fol- 
lowed by Bess and Wheeler with their arms full of wrapped presents. We all 
gathered around, smiling and talking and hugging and laughing.The boys 
were noisy as a crowd until Virgil said, "Now, Andy and Henry, you remem- 
ber our rule-I get half of what you get, and you get half of what I get." And 
then they got noisier, Henry offering Virgil one of his pistols, Andy back- 
ing up to keep both of his. And then all three of them went to the kitchen 
to smell the cooking and show their pistols to Nettie and Aunt Fanny. 

Hearing the commotion, Ernest Finley came down from his room. 
Ernest had been wounded in the First World War and walked on crutches. 
He was a woodworker and a carpenter, a thoughtful, quiet-speaking man 
who usually worked alone.The Catlett boys loved him because of his work 
and his tools and his neat shop and the long bedtime stories he told them 
when they came to visit. 



FROM HANNAH COUTLER 191 



Miss Ora came, still alert to see that I called her "Auntie," with Aunt 
Lizzie and Uncle Homer Lord, who had come down to Hargrave the day 
before from Indianapolis. The Lords weren't kin to the Feltners at all, 
except that Aunt Lizzie and Mrs. Feltner had been best friends when they 
were girls— which, Aunt Lizzie said, was as close kin as you could get. 

And then Virgil and I and the boys with their pistols drove out the 
Bird's Branch road to Uncle Jack Beechum's place— where he had been 
"batching it," as he said, since the death of his wife— and brought him to our 
house. He was the much younger brother of Mr. Feltner's mother, Nancy 
Beechum Feltner. Mr. Feltner's father, Ben, had been a father and a friend 
to Uncle Jack, who now was in a way the head of the family, though he 
never claimed such authority. Everybody looked up to him and loved him 
and, as sometimes was necessary, put up with him. 

Uncle Jack didn't try to have dignity, he just had it. A man of great 
strength in his day, he walked now with a cane, bent a little at the hips but 
still straight-backed. He was a big man, work-brittle, and there was no fool- 
ishness about him. 

You would have thought Henry would not have dared to do it, but as 
we were going from the car to the house he ran in front of Uncle Jack and 
shot at him with his pistols. I didn't think Uncle Jack would see anything 
funny in that, but he did. He gave a great snort of delight. He said, "That 
boy '11 put the cat in the churn." 

And so we all were there. 

To get the children calmed down before dinner and so the little girls 
could have a nap afterwards, we opened the presents right away. The old 
parlor was crowded with the tree and the people and the presents and the 
pretty wrapping papers flying about. Nettie Banion and Joe and Aunt 
Fanny sat in the doorway, waiting to receive the presents everybody had 
brought for them.The boys sat beside Virgil, who was making a big to-do 
over their presents, in which he was still claiming half-interest. The boys 
were a little unsure about this, but they loved his carrying on, and they sat 
as close to him as they could get. 

There were sixteen of us around the long table in the dining room. The 
table was so beautiful when we came in that it seemed almost a shame not 



192 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



to just stand and look at it. Mrs. Feltner had put on her best tablecloth and 
her good dishes and silverware that she never used except for company. 
And on the table at last, after our long preparations, were our ham, our 
turkey and dressing, and our scalloped oysters under their brown crust. 
There was a cut glass bowl of cranberry sauce. There were mashed potatoes 
and gravy, green beans and butter beans, corn pudding, and hot rolls. On 
the sideboard were our lovely cakes on cake stands and a big pitcher of cus- 
tard that would be served with whipped cream. 

It looked too good to touch, let alone eat, and yet of course we ate. 
Grandmam sat at Mr. Feltner's right hand at his end of the table, and 
Uncle Jack sat at Mrs. Feltner's right hand at her end. Virgil and I sat oppo- 
site Bess and Wheeler at the center. And the children in their chairs and 
high chairs were portioned out among the grownups, no two together. 

Every meal at the Feltners was good, for Mrs. Feltner and Nettie 
Banion both were fine cooks, but this one was extra good, and there were 
many compliments. Of all the compliments Uncle Jack's were the best, 
though he only increased the compliments of other people. He ate with 
great hunger and relish, and it was a joy to watch him. When somebody 
would say, "That is a wonderful ham" or "This dressing is perfect," Uncle 
Jack would solemnly shake his head and say, "Ay Lord, it is that!" And his 
words fell upon the table like a blessing. 

Beyond that, he said little, and Grandmam too had little to say, but 
whatever they said was gracious. To have the two of them there, at op- 
posite corners of the table, with their long endurance in their faces, and 
their present affection and pleasure, was a blessing of another kind. 



from Andy Catlett 



Now Andy Catlett is speaking as an aging man looking back to the Christmastime 
of 1943 when he first traveled away from his parents alone. He went by bus ten 
miles to visit, first, his grandma and grandpa Catlett who lived on the Bird's Branch 
road near PortWilliam, and then his granny and granddaddy Feltner who lived on 
one of the outer edges of PortWilliam itself. This passage and the two that follow are 
from Andy Catlett: Early Travels. Here he has just arrived and is visiting with 
Grandma Catlett in her kitchen. 

RURAL ELECTRIFICATION WAS on its way, I suppose, for it would soon 
arrive, but it had not arrived yet. On the back porch there was a large 
icebox that, when ice was available, preserved leftovers and cooled the milk 
in the summer. That and the battery-powered radio and the telephone were 
the only modern devices in the house. Its old economy of the farm house- 
hold was still intact. The supply lines ran to the kitchen from the henhouse 
and garden, cellar and smokehouse, cropland and pasture. On the kitchen 
table were two quart jars of green beans, a quart jar of applesauce, and a 
pint jar of what I knew to be the wild black raspberries that abounded in 
the thickets and woods edges of that time. I thought, "Pie!" 
"Are you going to make a pie?" I asked. 
"Hmh!" she said. "Maybe. Would you like to have a pie?" 
And I said, with my best manners, "Yes, mam." 

She was soon done with the potatoes. She shut the draft on the stove, 
taming the fire, changed the water on the potatoes, clapped a lid onto the 
pot, and set it on the stove to boil. She got out another pot, emptied the 



193 



194 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



beans into it, added salt, some pepper, and a fine piece of fat pork. She was 
talking at large, commenting on her work, telling what she had learned 
from relatives' letters and Christmas cards and from listening in on the 
party line. I was up and following her around by then, to make sure I got 
the benefit of everything. 

She washed her hands at the washstand by the back door and dried 
them. I followed her into the cool pantry and watched as she measured out 
flour and lard and the other ingredients and began making the dough for 
a pie crust. She rolled out the dough to the right thickness, pressed it into 
a pie pan, and, holding the pan on the fingertips of her left hand, passed 
a knife around its edge to carve off the surplus dough. 

As she went about her preparations for dinner, she was commenting to 
herself, with grunts of determination or approval, on her progress. I knew 
even then that it was a wonder to see her at her work, and I know it more 
completely now. Her kitchen would be counted a poor thing by modern 
standards. There was of course no electrical equipment at all. The cooking 
utensils, excepting the invincible iron skillet and griddle, were chipped or 
dented or patched. The kitchen knives were worn lean with sharpening. 
Everything was signed with the wear of a lifetime or more. She was a fine 
cook. She did not do much in the way of exact measurement. She seasoned 
to taste. She mixed by experience and to the right consistency. The dough 
for a pie crust or biscuits, for instance, had to be neither too flabby nor too 
stiff; it was right when it felt right. She did not own a cookbook or a writ- 
ten recipe. 

Meanwhile, she had prepared the raspberries, adding flour and sugar 
to the juice and heating it in a saucepan. Now she poured berries and 
juice into the dough-lined pan. She balled up the surplus dough, worked 
it briskly with her hands on the broken marble dresser top that she used 
for such work, sprinkled flour over it, rolled it flat, and then she sliced it 
rapidly into strips, which she laid in a beautiful lattice over the filling. As 
a final touch she sprinkled over the top a thin layer of sugar that in the 
heat of the oven would turn crisp and brown. And then she slid the pie 
into the oven. 



FROM ANDY CATLETT 195 



She was being extravagant with the sugar for my sake, as I was more or 
less aware, and as I took for granted. But knowledge grows with age, and 
gratitude grows with knowledge. Now I am as grateful to her as I should 
have been then, and I am troubled with love for her, knowing how she was 
wrung all her life between her cherished resentments and her fierce affec- 
tions. A peculiar sorrow hovered about her, and not only for the inevitable 
losses and griefs of her years; it came also from her settled conviction of the 
tendency of things to be unsatisfactory, to fail to live up to expectation, to 
fall short. She was haunted, I think, by the suspicion of a comedown always 
lurking behind the best appearances. I wonder now if she had ever read 
Paradise Lost. That poem, with its cosmos of Heaven and Hell and Paradise 
and the Fallen World, was a presence felt by most of her generation, if only 
by way of preachers who had read it. Whether or not she had read it for 
herself, the lostness of Paradise was the prime fact of her world, and she 
felt it keenly. 

Once the pie was out of the way, she went ahead and made biscuit 
dough, flattened it with her rolling pin, cut out the biscuits, and laid them 
into the pans ready for the oven when the time would come. 

She had cooked breakfast, strained the morning milk, made the beds, 
set the house to rights, washed the breakfast dishes, and cleaned up the 
kitchen before I got there. Now she let me help her, and we carried the 
crocks of morning milk from the back porch down into the cellar, and 
brought the crocks of last night's milk up from the cellar to the kitchen for 
skimming. 

Now it is noon of the same day. Andy has brought in the newspaper from the mail- 
box out at the road. 

I WENT AROUND the house and in at the kitchen door, pried off my over- 
shoes, handed the paper to Grandma, took off my wraps, and washed my 
hands. 

"Try combing that hair of yours," Grandma said. "Nobody ever saw the 
like. It's a regular straw stack." 

Knowing it would do no good, I took the comb from the shelf where 
the water bucket sat and passed it several times through my hair. 



196 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



Grandma watched me, and then she laughed. "You are the limit!" Her 
laugh was affectionate and indulgent, and yet it was a laugh with a history, 
conveying her perfected assurance that some things were hopeless. "Well, 
give up," she finally said. "Come and eat." 

She had made a splendid dinner, a feast, little affected by wartime 
stringencies, which, except for the rationing of coffee and sugar, were little 
felt in such households. It hadn't been long since hog-killing, and so there 
was not only a platter of fresh sausage but also a bowl of souse soaking in 
vinegar.There was a bowl of sausage gravy, another of mashed potatoes, 
another of green beans, another of apple sauce. There was a pan of hot bis- 
cuits, to be buttered or gravied, and another in the oven. There was a hand- 
some cake of freshly churned butter, the top marked in squares neatly 
carved with the edge of the butter paddle. There was a pitcher of butter- 
milk and one of sweet milk. And finally there was the pie, still warm, the 
top crust crisp and sugary and brown. 

Oh, I ate as one eats who has not eaten for days, as if my legs were hol- 
low, as if I were bigger inside than outside, and Grandma urged me on as 
if I were her champion in a tournament of eating. 

Grandpa began the meal protesting that he was not hungry, but he ate, 
as Grandma said, "with a coming appetite," and when it came it came in 
force. Before my time he had ridden horseback the five miles to Smallwood 
where his friend the atheist doctor Gib Holston had pulled all his teeth, 
but he "gummed it" as fast as I could chew with teeth, and he had more 
capacity. 

We ate and said little, for all of us were hungry. The food, as I see now 
but did not then, looked beautiful laid out before us on the table. And 
never then did I know that it was laid out in such profusion in honor of 
me. It was offered to me out of the loneliness of Grandma's life, out of her 
disappointments, her craving for small comforts and pleasures beyond her 
reach, to which Grandpa was indifferent. When I had washed down the last 
bite of my second piece of pie with a final swallow of milk, my stomach was 
as tight as a tick. I am sure I said "That was good." I may even have said 
"Thank you," for I was ever conscious that I was traveling alone and there- 
fore in need of my manners. But time has taught me greater thanks. 



FROM ANDY CATLETT 197 



And here Andy is visiting his mothers parents, Granny and Granddaddy Feltner, in 
PortWilliam. 

GRANDDADDY HAD gone down into town after breakfast, I didn't know 
what for. But I knew he was on the bank board and was trusted, and peo- 
ple depended on him for things. When he got back to the house, he came 
on to the dining room door and looked in. 
"Come on, son. Time to go to work." 

I knew he wanted me to go with him, and I sort of wanted to, but I 
knew too that it was a bitter morning outside, and mostly I didn't want to 
go. The weather made it lovely to imagine a whole morning snug in the 
house, listening to the sounds of housekeeping and cooking and the 
women talking. 

"Well," I said, "I think I'd rather just stay here." 

I have reason to believe that he would not have accepted that reply 
from my mother or Uncle Virgil when they were young. But I was differ- 
ent. I was his grandson, more my parents' responsibility than his, and, after 
all, still a boy. 

He just laughed a little to himself and said, "Well. All right." I heard 
him go through the house and out the back door. 

But it was not long until Granny came in. She said in her gentle way, 
"Andy, your granddaddy has some work that he needs you to help him 
with," and I knew I had to go. 

She had a promptitude of goodness that could be just fierce. She knew 
in an instant when I was dishonest or thoughtless or wrong. Much of my 
growing up, it seems to me now, was quietly required of me by her. She 
would correct me-"Listen to Granny. I expected something better from 
you"— and it would be as if in my mind a pawl had dropped into a notch; 
there was to be no going back. 

I went and got my outdoor things, put them on, and went out the back 
door. It was cold, and to make things worse a few freezing raindrops were 
coming down in a slant along the raw wind. I walked through the chicken 
yard where a few of Granddaddy 's old hens were standing around with 
their tails drooped, looking miserable. They looked like I felt. I was full of 



198 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



reluctance and embarrassment and shrunken in my clothes from the cold. 
Where Granddaddy was I had no idea, for I had not asked. I went through 
the gate on the far end of the chicken yard and into the field behind the 
barn, listening all the time. 

And then I heard Joe Banion speak in the driveway of the barn: "Come 
up." And he came out, standing on a hay wagon drawn by his team of 
mules, old Mary and old Jim. "Whoa-ho!" he said when he saw me. "I reck- 
on you just as well get on." 

"I reckon I just as well," I said, and I got on. 

Joe drove up to the tobacco barn on the highest part of the ridge. 
When we came even with the front of the barn Joe stopped the team again. 
"They inside," he told me. I jumped down and he drove on. 

I didn't know who "they" would be, but when I went through the front 
door, standing wide open to let in the light, I saw that they were 
Granddaddy and Burley Coulter. 

The Coulters, Burley and his brother, Jarrat, had housed tobacco in 
that barn, but now they had emptied it. What Granddaddy and Burley 
were doing that morning was preparing the barn for the lambing that was 
due to begin in just a few days. Because they had used the barn, this was 
partly the Coulters' responsibility, and Burley had come to help. I was still 
feeling ashamed and a little odd because of my refusal, and so when I had 
stepped through the door I just stopped. 

There was a large rick of baled alfalfa in one corner of the barn, put 
there to be handy to feed the lambing ewes. Granddaddy and Burley were 
building a low partition around it to keep the ewes from ruining it before 
they could eat it. Granddaddy was starting to nail up a board, and Burley 
was sorting through a stack of old lumber. 

The first to notice me was Granddaddy. He said, "Hello, son." 

And then Burley turned to look and said, "Well! If it ain't Andy!" 

It was a moment not possible to forget. Tom Coulter, who not long ago 
had been killed in the fighting in Italy, was Burley 's nephew. Part of the 
blood that had been shed in that bad year of 1943 had been Tom Coulter's. 
I had not seen Burley since the news of Tom's death had come. 

I didn't have grown-up manners, and I didn't know what to say. When 



FROM ANDY CATLETT 199 



Burley spoke to me, it was as if he was not just greeting or welcoming me, 
but receiving me into his tenderness for Tom. It put a lump in my throat. 
He came over, taking off his right glove, and shook my hand. 

He said, "How you making it, old boy?" 

I just nodded, afraid if I said "Fine" I would cry. 

Granddaddy said, "Andy, pick up the other end of this board, honey." 

I picked it up and held it while he nailed his end. And then he came 
over and nailed my end. We did the same with the next board. And so I 
was helping. All through the morning they kept finding ways for me to 
help. They let me belong there at work with them. They kept me busy. And 
I experienced a beautiful change that was still new to me then but is old 
and familiar now. I went from reluctance and dread to interest in what we 
were doing, and then to pleasure in it. I got warm. 

We finished the barrier around the hay rick. We picked up everything 
that was out of place or in the way. We made the barn neat. Joe returned 
with a load of straw from the straw stack. And then we bedded the barn, 
carrying forkloads of straw from the wagon and shaking it out level and 
deep over the whole floor, replacing the old fragrance of tobacco with the 
new fragrance of clean straw. Granddaddy had some long panels that 
would be used, as soon as needed, to portion the barn between the ewes 
with lambs and those still to lamb. We repaired the panels and propped 
them against the walls where they would be handy. We unstacked the 
mangers and lined them up in a row down the center of the driveway. 
Along one wall we set up the four-by-four-foot lambing pens where the ewes 
with new lambs would be confined and watched over until the lambs were 
well started and strong— "the maternity ward," Granddaddy called it. 

The men were letting me help sometimes even when I could see I was 
slowing them down. We transformed the barn from a tobacco barn recall- 
ing last summer's crop to a sheep barn expecting next year's lambs. In our 
work we could feel the new year coming, the days lengthening, the time of 
birth and growth returning, and this seemed to bring a happiness to every- 
body, in spite of the war and people's griefs and fears.The last thing we did 
was clean up the stripping room. It would be a sort of hospital, where 
Granddaddy, when he would be watching in the cold nights, could build a 



200 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



fire and help with a difficult birth, or pen a ewe with weak lambs until the 
lambs had sucked and were well dried, or keep orphan lambs until they got 
a good start. 

When we were done at last, Granddaddy looked at his watch and then 
at me. "Well," he said, "could you eat a little something?" 

The whole morning had gone by already, and I had not thought of 
hunger, but now when I thought of it I was hungry. I said, "I could eat a lot 
of something." 

We laughed, and Burley said, "His belly thinks his throat's been cut." 

"Burley," Granddaddy said, "won't you come have a bite of dinner with us?" 

And Burley said, "Naw, Mat. Thank you. I left some dinner on the 
stove at home. I better go see about it." 

Joe took the team and wagon back to the feed barn then, and I went 
with Granddaddy to drive Burley out to his house. 

By the time we got back and washed, everybody was in the kitchen. 
Nettie was finishing up at the stove and Granny and Hannah were putting 
the food on the table. The smell of it seemed fairly to hollow me out inside. 
We had sausage and gravy and mashed potatoes, just like at Grandma's. 
Granny's sausage was seasoned differently but was just as good. And we 
had, besides, hominy and creamed butter beans and, instead of biscuits, 
hoecake— one already on the table, sliced, another on the griddle— a pitcher 
of fresh milk, coffee for the grown-ups, and again all the Christmas 
desserts, and again, for me, ice cream. 

"Save room," Granny said again. 

And I said, "I'm going to have plenty of room." 

I had more room even than I thought. 

Hannah said, "Do you think he'll leave us anything to eat tomorrow?" 
"I don't know," Granddaddy said. "We may have to skip a day or two." 



from "Misery" 



Here again Andy Catlett is speaking in old age, again remembering his Catlett 
grandparents, but this is from a short story.The time is 1945. 

THE HOUSEHOLD EMBODIED and was sustained by an agricultural order, 
resting upon the order of time and nature, that was at once demand- 
ing and consoling. Because this order was the order of the house, a child 
could be happy in it. 

But the time was coming, was already arriving, when that order would 
be disvalued and taken apart piece by piece. I had come along just in time 
to glimpse the old order when it was still somewhat intact. I had played or 
idled in blacksmith shops while the smiths shod horses or mules, and built 
from raw iron and wood many of the simple farming tools still in use. I had 
gone along with the crews of neighbors as they followed the binder in the 
grainfields, gathering the bound sheaves into shocks, stopping to catch the 
young rabbits that ran from the still-standing wheat or barley. I had 
watched as they fed load after load of sheaves into the threshing machine 
and sacked and hauled away the grain. And I had been on hand when the 
sweated crews washed on the back porch and sat down to harvest meals 
equal to Christmas dinners, even in wartime with no sugar for the iced tea, 
to eat big and tell stories and laugh. 

And then there came a day when Grandma, old and ill and without 
help, was not up to the task of cooking for a threshing crew, and my father 
could see that she was not. He had taken time off from his law office to 
splice out Grandpa, who also was not equal to the day. 



201 



202 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



"It's all right," my father said, comforting Grandma. "I'll take care of it." 

And he did take care of it, for he was a man who refused to be at a loss, 
and he was capable. He went and bought a great pile of ground beef and 
sacks full of packaged buns. He fired up the kitchen stove and, overpower- 
ing Grandma's attempts to help, fried hamburgers enough, and more than 
enough, to feed the crew of hungry men and their retinue of hungry boys. 
It was adequate. It was even admirable, in its way, I could see that. But I 
could see also that something old and good was turning, or had turned, 
profoundly wrong. An old propriety that I knew was not mine had been 
offended. I could not have said this at the time, but I felt it; I felt it entire- 
ly.There was my father in the kitchen, cooking, not like any cook I had ever 
seen, but like himself, all concentration and haste, going at a big job that 
had to be done, nothing lovely about it. And there was the crew sitting 
down, not to a proper harvest meal, but to hamburgers that I knew they 
associated, as I did, with town life, with hamburger joints. 

Grandma and Grandpa had achieved their threescore years and ten 
and more; their strength had become labor and sorrow.The life they had 
lived, the old season-governed life of the country, was passing away as they 
watched. No threshing machine or threshing crew would come to their 
place again, and there would be no more big straw stacks for a boy to climb 
up and slide down. The combines had arrived, their service to be pur- 
chased by mere money. 



from The Memory of Old Jack 



It is September 1952, during the tobacco cutting on the Feltner place. The tradition 
of work-swapping has continued until now, as it will continue, slowly raveling out, 
for another thirty or so years. The men have gathered to harvest the crop and the 
women to feed them dinner. Margaret Feltner is getting on in years and Hannah- 
who, after Virgil Feltner's death in World War II, married Nathan Coulter— is preg- 
nant. But Mary Venn, as soon as dinner is over and the dishes done, will go out to 
work the rest of the day with the men. At the start of this passage Hannah has 
found Old Jack Beechum in the barbershop, where he has been sleeping and dream- 
ing, and she is bringing him to the Feltner house for dinner. 

THEY WALK SLOWLY up the street toward Mat's, Hannah holding to the 
old man's arm as if to be helped, but in reality helping him. And yet 
she knows that, by taking that arm so graciously bent at her service, she is 
being helped. She is sturdily accompanied by his knowledge, in which she 
knows that she is whole. In his gaze she feels herself to be not just physical- 
ly but historically a woman, one among generations, bearing into mystery 
the dark seed. She feels herself completed by that as she could not be com- 
pleted by the desire of a younger man. As they walk, she tells him such 
news as there is: how they all are, where they are working, what they have 
got done, what they have left to do. From time to time she stops, as if to 
give all her attention to her story, to allow him a moment of rest. But she 
is glad to prolong the walk. She is moved by him, pleased to stand in his 
sight, whose final knowledge is womanly, who knows that all human labor 
passes into mystery, who has been faithful unto death to the life of his 



203 



204 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



fields to no end that he will know in this world. As for Old Jack, he listens 
to the sound of her voice, strong and full of hope, knowing and near to joy, 
that pleases him and tells him what he wants to know. He nods and smiles, 
encouraging her to go on. Occasionally he praises her, in that tone of final 
judgment old age has given him. "You're a fine woman.You're all right," he 
says. And his tone implies: Believe it of yourself forever. 

They are crossing Mat's yard now, and suddenly Old Jack can smell din- 
ner. It is strong, and it stirs him. It changes his mind. He steps faster. He is 
leaving the world of his old age and entering a stronger, younger world. He 
is going into the very heart of that world where labor's hunger is fed with 
its increase. That is the order that he knows, and knows only and finally: 
that complexity of returns between work and hunger. 

They turn the corner of the house into sight of the back porch, and 
there are all the men just come in. Two washpans and two kettles of hot 
water have been brought out and set down. Little Margaret stands nearby, 
holding a towel. Lightning and Mat's grandson, Andy Catlett, are washing 
at the edge of the porch, leaning over the pans. Mat is sitting in a willow 
rocking chair on the porch with Mattie on his lap. The others— Burley, 
Jarrat, Nathan, Elton-stand or squat in the yard beyond the porch, smok- 
ing, waiting their turns. Their shirts are wet with sweat. Their hands and 
the fronts of their clothes are dark with tobacco gum. They smell of sweat 
and tobacco and the earth of the field. In the stance of all of them there is 
relish of the stillness that comes after heavy labor. They have come to rest, 
and their stillness now, because of the long afternoon's work yet ahead of 
them, is more intense, more deeply felt, more carefully enjoyed, than that 
which will come at the day's end. Even Mat, who ordinarily would be car- 
rying on some sort of play with Mattie, is sitting still, his hands at rest on 
the chair arms. Mattie is leaning against his shoulder, nearly asleep. Only 
Burley is talking, though he keeps otherwise as carefully still as the others. 
He is directing a mixture of banter and praise at Lightning's back. It is a bill 
of goods designed, as the rest of them well know, to keep Lightning on 
hand. Under the burden of such a stretch of hard work his customary brag- 
ging has given way to periods of sulkiness. 

"Why, look at the arm on him," Burley is saying. "Look at the muscle the 



FROM THE MEMORY OF OLD JACK 205 



fellow's got. Damn, he can barely get his sleeve rolled up over it. No won- 
der I can't stay with him." 

The others grin and wink. The fact is that, left to himself, Lightning is 
slow. But all week Burley has been working constantly at his heel, bragging 
on him, threatening to pass him, never quite doing it— and has succeeded 
in driving him almost up with Elton and Nathan, who are the best of them. 

Lightning straightens from his washing and dries hands and face on 
the towel that Little Margaret holds out to him. He is doing his best to stay 
aloof from Burley 's talk, but it gets to him, and he touches lovingly the mus- 
cle of his right arm. 

"He put it on me this morning, Uncle Jack," Burley says, seeing the old 
man coming around the house. "I tried him, but I couldn't shake him." 

"Go on and wash," he says to Jarrat. "I got to finish my smoke." He 
stands bent forward a little at the hips, hand on the small of his back. He 
seems to be hurting a little. He probably is, but he is playing on it too, par- 
odying an aged and a beaten man. He looks afar, soliloquizing about his 
defeat. "Nawsir! Couldn't handle him! Too few biscuits and too many years 
have done made the difference." 

"Ay Lord, he's a good one!" Old Jack says, seeing the point. He knows 
where that Lightning would be if somebody was not crowding him all the 
time. Somewhere asleep. But he shakes his head in approbation of Burley 's 
praise. "He's got the right look about him." 

"You're right, old scout," Burley says. "He's the pride of Landing 
Branch, and no doubt about it. But I believe I smell a biscuit in the wind, 
and maybe a ham, and that may make a difference this afternoon. When I 
go back out there I aim to be properly fed. Oh, I may not get ahead of him, 
but I'll be where he can hear me coming. Ham and biscuits!" he says. And 
he sings: 

How many biscuits can you eat? 
Forty-nine and a ham of meat 
This mornin'. 



Lightning is at work now with a comb, putting the finishing touches to his 



206 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



wave and ducktail, a sculpture not destined to survive the next motion of 
his head. There is an arrogance in his eye and jaw and the line of his 
mouth, based not upon any excellence of his own but upon his contempt 
for excellence: If he is not the best man in the field, then he is nevertheless 
equal to the best man by the perfection of his scorn, for the best man and 
for the possibility that is incarnate in him. Old Jack studies Lightning's 
face-he recognizes it; he has known other men who have worn it, too 
many-and then he grunts, "Hunhl" and looks away. 

Jarrat and Elton finish washing and Burley and Nathan take their 
places. Hannah picks up Mattie, who has fallen asleep in Mat's lap, and 
takes him in to his napping place on the parlor floor. Little Margaret has 
wandered off to play. 

Now Mat gets up and he and Old Jack wash.When they have finished 
with the towel, Mat hangs it on the back of the rocking chair. 

"Let's go eat it," he says. He holds open the kitchen door and they file 
in past him, Old Jack first and the others following.There is a general 
exchange of greetings between the men and the three women. 

Old Jack takes his place at the head of the table. "Sit down, boys," he 
says, and they pull out their chairs and sit down. Mat is at the foot of the 
table. At the sides, to Old Jack's right, are Elton and Lightning and Andy 
and, to his left, Burley and Nathan and Jarrat. They pass various loaded 
platters and bowls, filling their plates. 

They fall silent now, eating with the concentration of hunger. The 
women keep the dishes moving around the table as necessary and keep the 
glasses filled with iced tea. 

"Lay it away, boys," Old Jack says. "It's fine and there's plenty of it." 

Following his lead, the others praise the food, the ones whose wives 
have cooked being careful to praise the cooking of the other women. 

In the presence of that hunger and that eager filling, Old Jack eats well 
himself. But his thoughts go to the other men, and he watches them. He 
watches the older ones— Mat and Jarrat and Burley— sensing their weariness 
and their will to endure, troubling about them and admiring them. He 
watches the five proven men, whom he loves with the satisfaction of thor- 
ough knowledge and long trust, praising and blessing them in his mind. He 



FROM THE MEMORY OF OLD JACK 207 



watches them with pleasure so keen it is almost pain. 

And he watches the boy, Andy, whom he loves out of kinship and be- 
cause he is not afraid of work and because of his good, promising mind, 
but with uneasiness also because he has so little meat on his bones and has 
a lot to go through, a lot to make up his mind about. 

And he watches Lightning, whom he does not love. That one, he 
thinks, will be hard put to be worth what he will eat. For he is one who 
believes in a way out. As long as he has two choices, or thinks he has, he 
will never do his best or think of the possibility of the best. 

Old Jack shakes his head. "See that that Andy gets plenty to eat," he 
tells Mat. 

"Don't you worry. I'm going to take care of this boy," Mat says. And he 
gives Andy a squeeze and a pat on the shoulder. 

"We going to miss old Andy when he's gone," Burley says. 

The edge is off their hunger now, and they give attention to Andy, for 
whom this is the summer's last workday. Tomorrow he will be leaving to 
begin his first year of college. 

"We'll be looking around here for the old boy," Burley says, "and he'll 
done be gone.They'll say, 'Where's the old long boy that could load the 
wagon so good? Where's that one that used to house the top tiers?' And 
we'll say,'01d Andy ain't here no more. He's up there to the university, 
studying his books.'" 

"Studying the girls," Nathan says, grinning and winking at Hannah. 

"He'll be all right with the girls if he wants to be," Hannah says. "I'm a 
better judge of that than you." 

"You do all right with Kirby, don't you, Andy, hon?" Mary Penn says. 

"Yeah, if old Kirby's going to have any say-so, he better keep his mind 
on his books while he's up there," Burley says. "He don't, she'll kick over 
the beehive, I expect." 

'You keep your mind on your books anyhow, Andy," Jarrat says, look- 
ing gravely across the table at the boy, his gaze ponderous and straight 
under thick brows. "Mind your books, and amount to something." 

"Andy," Elton says, "you'll get full of book learning and fine ways up 



208 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



there, and you won't have any more time for us here at all." 

Andy, who has been grinning at this commentary on his departure, 
now flushes with embarrassment. "Yes I will," he says, though he knows the 
inadequacy of such an avowal. The faith that Elton has called for, though 
he spoke in jest, will have to be proved. 

They all know it. Andy has not yet chosen among his choices. 

And then Mat says, "Well, he's learned some things here with us that 
he couldn't have learned in a school. A lot of his teachers there won't know 
them. And if he's the boy I think he is, he won't forget them." 

"Yessir!" Old Jack says. "By God, that's right!" 

Now all the plates are empty. The women gather them and stack them 
by the sink. They replace them with dishes of blackberry cobbler, still warm 
from the oven, covered with cold whipped cream. 

"You all can thank Andy for this," Hannah says. "I made it for him 
because it's his favorite." 

"Thank him!" Nathan says. "I'm mad as hell about it. When are you 
going to fix me something because it's my favorite?" 

Hannah grins. "Your time is coming," she says, "junior." 

The others laugh.The iced tea glasses are filled again.They take their 
time over the cobbler, talking idly now of the past, of other crops. 

The afternoon's work is near them, not to be put off much longer. Old 
Jack can feel it around him in the air, that dread of the heat and heaviness 
of the afternoon that even the strongest and the best man will suffer. But 
not for him anymore the going back to the field. No more for him the 
breaking sweat under the sun's blaze, the delight of skill and strength, and 
the pride. 



from Jayber Crow 



Jayber himself is speaking. From 1937 until 1969 he was the barber in Port 
William, living in the single room over his shop. Health regulations requiring hot 
running water put him out of business there. Now he is living, and still barbering, 
in a remote camp house on the river. Not much is said here about food, though the 
occasion is partly a meal. But maybe the real subject is the free exchanging of affec- 
tion and help that makes what Burley Coulter calls "the membership" of 
PortWilliam. 

TO GET MY own hair cut, I had continued to go down to Hargrave. 
When I lived in Port William, this was easy enough to arrange. I 
would hear that somebody was going and would speak for a ride. From the 
house on the river, it was not so easy. Sometimes it would come to hitch- 
hiking, which could take half a day. I happened to mention this to Danny. 

He said, "Why, Jayber, you don't need to go to Hargrave to get your hair 
cut. Lyda can cut it." 

It was evening. He had finished running his lines and was going home. 
"Come on," he said. 

So we went up to his truck and I rode home with him. 

"Lyda," he said, "Jayber here needs to get his hair cut." 

She said, "Well, he'll have to eat his supper first. I can't stop now." 

I said, "Oh, now, I hate to put you to the trouble." 

"One more mouth won't make any difference here," she said. 

"Naw, Jayber," Burley called from the porch swing, "it won't be any trou- 



209 



210 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



ble. Come on up. I'll have supper on the table in a few minutes." 

Lyda took a swipe at his shoulder with the rag she had in her hand. 
"You'll have it on the table! That'll be a fair fine day in Hell!" 

"That's where they've got something cooking all the time," Burley said. 
"Come on up, Jayber." 

By then all the children and dogs knew there was a stranger on the 
place, and they had come to look. They all crowded around me as if maybe 
I had my pockets full of candy. 

"Get back! Get back!" Danny said. "Give a man room to walk!" He 
made a parting motion with his hands. 

Children and dogs fell back to each side like the waters of the Red Sea, 
leaving a sort of aisle that Danny and I walked through to the washstand 
by the rain barrel at the corner of the porch. Danny picked up the wash 
pan, smote the surface of the water in the barrel with the bottom of the pan 
to drive the wigglers down, dipped the pan half full of water, set it down 
on the washstand, and stepped aside, gesturing welcome with his hand. 
"There's soap and a towel if you'd like to wash up," he said to me, and then 
to the children and dogs who had clustered around again, "Get back!" 

The children and dogs fell back, never ceasing to watch me. I washed 
up, threw the water out, dipped the pan for Danny, and made my way 
amongst the children and dogs up onto the porch. "Sit down, Jayber," 
Burley said, and I sat down. 

When he had washed, Danny refilled the pan and stood there watch- 
ing while the children washed, the bigger ones seeing to the littler ones, 
who wanted to splash more than wash. Danny said, "Keep your hands off 
of them dogs, now, till after supper." 

You might think that so many young children would make a consider- 
able uproar at a meal, but when Lyda called us in to supper those children 
(from Will, who was fourteen, right down to Rosie, who was four) went in 
and sat down in their places and never made a peep. I thought at first that 
that probably was because I was there, but in fact it was pretty much accord- 
ing to rule. But this wasn't spiritlessness: It was discipline. Out from under 
Lyda's gaze, the children were noisy enough. When Reuben and the two 
girls were little, they talked all the time, all at the same time, in high chirps, 



FROM JAYBER CROW 211 



like a tree full of sparrows. 

When the meal was over, the children scraped and stacked the dishes, 
which Burley then washed and Will dried and put away. 

There was a running joke between Burley and Lyda about Burley's 
reluctance and incompetence at housework, but of course Burley had lived 
alone for a long time before Danny and Lyda came, and he could do all the 
household work, if not to Lyda's taste at least well enough. When they 
came, since it was his house, he might have treated them as the beneficiar- 
ies of his hospitality, but instead he made himself their guest. They 
responded, as maybe they didn't have to do, by being hospitable to him. He 
was, I think, a good guest, helping especially Lyda in every way he could. 
She caught his trick of dealing with this arrangement and their large affec- 
tion for each other as an endlessly branching joke, in which they said the 
opposite of what they meant. If Burley complained that he was behind in 
his housework because she was always underfoot and in the way, he meant 
that she was anything but in the way and he was thankful to have her there. 
If Lyda said that it would have been a mercy if she had married one hus- 
band instead of two bachelors, that meant that she loved them both more 
than enough to put up with them. And so on. 

While Burley and Will did the dishes and Danny and Royal and 
Coulter and Fount went out to feed the dogs and do a few last chores (the 
children having milked and fed before supper), Lyda gave me my haircut. 
The sight of their mother cutting a stranger's hair was so shocking that 
Rachel and Rosie whispered and giggled throughout the operation, and 
Reuben could bear to watch only from under the table. 



from Hannah Coulter 



These two paragraphs return us to Hannah Coulter. It is the year 2000. Her sec- 
ond husband, Nathan, has died. Her grandsonVirgie—son of Margaret, daughter of 
Hannah and her first hushand,Virgil Feltner—has taken to disillusion and drugs, 
and has disappeared. Caleb is Hannah and Nathan's son. He is a scientist, a pro- 
fessor of agriculture in a university some distance away. Alice is his wife. 

EVEN OLD, YOUR husband is the young man you remember now. Even 
dead, he is the man you remember, not as he was but as he is, alive 
still in your love. Death is a sort of lens, though I used to think of it as a 
wall or a shut door. It changes things and makes them clear. Maybe it is the 
truest way of knowing this dream, this brief and timeless life. Sometimes 
when I try to remember Nathan, I can't see him exactly enough. Other 
times, when I haven't thought of him, he comes to me unbidden, and I see 
him more clearly, I think, than ever I did. Am I awake then, or there, or 
here? 

It is the fall of the year. We have had Thanksgiving. Caleb and Alice 
were here. And Margaret came, reconciled by now maybe to Virgie's ab- 
sence, but not one of us spoke of Virgie. I fixed a big dinner, enough to 
keep us all in leftovers for a while: a young gobbler that Coulter Branch 
shot and gave to me, dressing and gravy, mashed potatoes, green beans, 
corn pudding, hot rolls, a cushaw pie. We sat down to it, the four of us, like 
stray pieces of several puzzles. Nathan would have asked the blessing, and I 
should have, I tried to, but that turned out to be a silence I could not speak 
in. I only sat with my head down, while the others waited for me to say 



213 



214 BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 

something out loud. And then, to change the subject, I said, "Caleb, take 
a roll and pass 'em." 



The Pleasures of Eating 

(1989) 



MANY TIMES, AFTER I have finished a lecture on the decline of Americ- 
an farming and rural life, someone in the audience has asked, 
"What can city people do?" 

"Eat responsibly," I have usually answered. Of course, I have tried to 
explain what I meant by that, but afterwards I have invariably felt that there 
was more to be said than I had been able to say. Now I would like to 
attempt a better explanation. 

I begin with the proposition that eating is an agricultural act. Eating 
ends the annual drama of the food economy that begins with planting and 
birth. Most eaters, however, are no longer aware that this is true. They 
think of food as an agricultural product, perhaps, but they do not think of 
themselves as "consumers." If they think beyond that, they recognize that 
they are passive consumers. They buy what they want— or what they have 
been persuaded to want— within the limits of what they can get. They pay, 
mostly without protest, what they are charged. And they mostly ignore cer- 
tain critical questions about the quality and the cost of what they are sold: 
How fresh is it? How pure or clean is it, how free of dangerous chemicals? 
How far was it transported, and what did transportation add to the cost? 
How much did manufacturing or packaging or advertising add to the cost? 
When the food product has been manufactured or "processed" or "pre- 
cooked," how has that affected its quality or price or nutritional value? 



215 



216 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



Most urban shoppers would tell you that food is produced on farms. 
But most of them do not know what farms, or what kinds of farms, or 
where the farms are, or what knowledge or skills are involved in farming. 
They apparently have little doubt that farms will continue to produce, but 
they do not know how or over what obstacles. For them, then, food is pret- 
ty much an abstract idea— something they do not know or imagine— until it 
appears on the grocery shelf or on the table. 

The specialization of production induces specialization of consump- 
tion. Patrons of the entertainment industry, for example, entertain them- 
selves less and less and have become more and more passively dependent 
on commercial suppliers. This is certainly true also of patrons of the food 
industry, who have tended more and more to be mere consumers— passive, 
uncritical, and dependent. Indeed, this sort of consumption may be said to 
be one of the chief goals of industrial production.The food industrialists 
have by now persuaded millions of consumers to prefer food that is already 
prepared. They will grow, deliver, and cook your food for you and (just like 
your mother) beg you to eat it. That they do not yet offer to insert it, 
prechewed, into your mouth is only because they have found no profitable 
way to do so. We may rest assured that they would be glad to find such a 
way. The ideal industrial food consumer would be strapped to a table with 
a tube running from the food factory directly into his or her stomach. 

Perhaps I exaggerate, but not by much.The industrial eater is, in fact, 
one who does not know that eating is an agricultural act, who no longer 
knows or imagines the connections between eating and the land, and who 
is therefore necessarily passive and uncritical— in short, a victim. When 
food, in the minds of eaters, is no longer associated with farming and with 
the land, then the eaters are suffering a kind of cultural amnesia that is mis- 
leading and dangerous. The current version of the "dream home" of the 
future involves "effortless" shopping from a list of available goods on a tel- 
evision monitor and heating precooked food by remote control. Of course, 
this implies and depends on a perfect ignorance of the history of the food 
that is consumed. It requires that the citizenry should give up their hered- 
itary and sensible aversion to buying a pig in a poke. It wishes to make the 
selling of pigs in pokes an honorable and glamorous activity. The dreamer 
in this dream home will perforce know nothing about the kind or quality 



THE PLEASURES OF EATING 217 



of this food, or where it came from, or how it was produced and prepared, 
or what ingredients, additives, and residues it contains-unless, that is, the 
dreamer undertakes a close and constant study of the food industry, in 
which case he or she might as well wake up and play an active and respon- 
sible part in the economy of food. 

There is, then, a politics of food that, like any politics, involves our free- 
dom. We still (sometimes) remember that we cannot be free if our minds 
and voices are controlled by someone else. But we have neglected to under- 
stand that we cannot be free if our food and its sources are controlled by 
someone else. The condition of the passive consumer of food is not a dem- 
ocratic condition. One reason to eat responsibly is to live free. 

But if there is a food politics, there are also a food esthetics and a food 
ethics, neither of which is dissociated from politics. Like industrial sex, 
industrial eating has become a degraded, poor, and paltry thing. Our 
kitchens and other eating places more and more resemble filling stations, 
as our homes more and more resemble motels. "Life is not very interest- 
ing," we seem to have decided. "Let its satisfactions be minimal, perfunc- 
tory, and fast." We hurry through our meals to go to work and hurry 
through our work in order to "recreate" ourselves in the evenings and on 
weekends and vacations. And then we hurry, with the greatest possible 
speed and noise and violence, through our recreation-for what? To eat the 
billionth hamburger at some fast-food joint hellbent on increasing the 
"quality" of our life? And all this is carried out in a remarkable oblivious- 
ness to the causes and effects, the possibilities and the purposes, of the life 
of the body in this world. 

One will find this obliviousness represented in virgin purity in the 
advertisements of the food industry, in which food wears as much makeup 
as the actors. If one gained one's whole knowledge of food from these 
advertisements (as some presumably do), one would not know that the var- 
ious edibles were ever living creatures, or that they all come from the soil, 
or that they were produced by work. The passive American consumer, sit- 
ting down to a meal of pre-prepared or fast food, confronts a platter cov- 
ered with inert, anonymous substances that have been processed, dyed, 
breaded, sauced, gravied, ground, pulped, strained, blended, prettified, 



218 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



and sanitized beyond resemblance to any part of any creature that ever 
lived. The products of nature and agriculture have been made, to all 
appearances, the products of industry. Both eater and eaten are thus in 
exile from biological reality. And the result is a kind of solitude, unprece- 
dented in human experience, in which the eater may think of eating as, 
first, a purely commercial transaction between him and a supplier and then 
as a purely appetitive transaction between him and his food. 

And this peculiar specialization of the act of eating is, again, of obvi- 
ous benefit to the food industry, which has good reasons to obscure the 
connection between food and farming. It would not do for the consumer 
to know that the hamburger she is eating came from a steer who spent 
much of his life standing deep in his own excrement in a feedlot, helping 
to pollute the local streams, or that the calf that yielded the veal cutlet on 
her plate spent its life in a box in which it did not have room to turn 
around. And, though her sympathy for the slaw might be less tender, she 
should not be encouraged to meditate on the hygienic and biological impli- 
cations of mile-square fields of cabbage, for vegetables grown in huge 
monocultures are dependent on toxic chemicals— just as animals in close 
confinement are dependent on antibiotics and other drugs. 

The consumer, that is to say, must be kept from discovering that, in the 
food industry-as in any other industry— the overriding concerns are not 
quality and health, but volume and price. For decades now the entire 
industrial food economy, from the large farms and feedlots to the chains of 
supermarkets and fast-food restaurants, has been obsessed with volume. It 
has relentlessly increased scale in order to increase volume in order (pre- 
sumably) to reduce costs. But as scale increases, diversity declines; as diver- 
sity declines, so does health; as health declines, the dependence on drugs 
and chemicals necessarily increases. As capital replaces labor, it does so by 
substituting machines, drugs, and chemicals for human workers and for the 
natural health and fertility of the soil.The food is produced by any means 
or any shortcut that will increase profits. And the business of the cosmeti- 
cians of advertising is to persuade the consumer that food so produced is 
good, tasty, healthful, and a guarantee of marital fidelity and long life. 

It is possible, then, to be liberated from the husbandry and wifery of 



THE PLEASURES OF EATING 219 



the old household food economy. But one can be thus liberated only by 
entering a trap (unless one sees ignorance and helplessness as the signs of 
privilege, as many people apparently do). The trap is the ideal of industri- 
alism: a walled city surrounded by valves that let merchandise in but no 
consciousness out. How does one escape this trap? Only voluntarily, the 
same way that one went in: by restoring one's consciousness of what is 
involved in eating, by reclaiming responsibility for one's own part in the 
food economy. One might begin with the illuminating principle of Sir 
Albert Howard's The Soil and Health, that we should understand "the whole 
problem of health in soil, plant, animal, and man as one great subject." 
Eaters, that is, must understand that eating takes place inescapably in the 
world, that it is inescapably an agricultural act, and that how we eat deter- 
mines, to a considerable extent, how the world is used. This is a simple way 
of describing a relationship that is inexpressibly complex. To eat responsi- 
bly is to understand and enact, so far as one can, this complex relationship. 
What can one do? Here is a list, probably not definitive: 

1. Participate in food production to the extent that you can. If you have a 
yard or even just a porch box or a pot in a sunny window, grow some- 
thing to eat in it. Make a little compost of your kitchen scraps and use 
it for fertilizer. Only by growing some food for yourself can you become 
acquainted with the beautiful energy cycle that revolves from soil to 
seed to flower to fruit to food to offal to decay, and around again.You 
will be fully responsible for any food that you grow for yourself, and you 
will know all about it. You will appreciate it fully, having known it all its 
life. 

2. Prepare your own food. This means reviving in your own mind and life 
the arts of kitchen and household. This should enable you to eat more 
cheaply, and it will give you a measure of "quality control" You will have 
some reliable knowledge of what has been added to the food you eat. 

3. Learn the origins of the food you buy, and buy the food that is produced 
closest to your home. The idea that every locality should be, as much as 
possible, the source of its own food makes several kinds of sense. The 
locally produced food supply is the most secure, the freshest, and the 
easiest for local consumers to know about and to influence. 



220 



BRINGING IT TO THE TABLE 



4. Whenever possible, deal directly with a local farmer, gardener, or 
orchardist. All the reasons listed for the previous suggestion apply here. 
In addition, by such dealing you eliminate the whole pack of merchants, 
transporters, processors, packagers, and advertisers who thrive at the 
expense of both producers and consumers. 

5. Learn, in self-defense, as much as you can of the economy and technol- 
ogy of industrial food production. What is added to food that is not 
food, and what do you pay for these additions? 

6. Learn what is involved in the best farming and gardening. 

7. Learn as much as you can, by direct observation and experience if pos- 
sible, of the life histories of the food species. 

The last suggestion seems particularly important to me. Many people are 
now as much estranged from the lives of domestic plants and animals 
(except for flowers and dogs and cats) as they are from the lives of the wild 
ones. This is regrettable, for these domestic creatures are in diverse ways 
attractive; there is much pleasure in knowing them. And farming, animal 
husbandry, horticulture, and gardening, at their best, are complex and 
comely arts; there is much pleasure in knowing them, too. 

It follows that there is great displeasure in knowing about a food econ- 
omy that degrades and abuses those arts and those plants and animals and 
the soil from which they come. For anyone who does know something of 
the modern history of food, eating away from home can be a chore. My 
own inclination is to eat seafood instead of red meat or poultry when I am 
traveling. Though I am by no means a vegetarian, I dislike the thought that 
some animal has been made miserable in order to feed me. If I am going 
to eat meat, I want it to be from an animal that has lived a pleasant, 
uncrowded life outdoors, on bountiful pasture, with good water nearby 
and trees for shade. And I am getting almost as fussy about food plants. I 
like to eat vegetables and fruits that I know have lived happily and health- 
ily in good soil, not the products of the huge, bechemicaled factory-fields 
that I have seen, for example, in the Central Valley of California.The indus- 
trial farm is said to have been patterned on the factory production line. In 
practice, it looks more like a concentration camp. 



THE PLEASURES OF EATING 221 



The pleasure of eating should be an extensive pleasure, not that of the 
mere gourmet. People who know the garden in which their vegetables have 
grown and know that the garden is healthy will remember the beauty of the 
growing plants, perhaps in the dewy first light of morning when gardens are 
at their best. Such a memory involves itself with the food and is one of the 
pleasures of eating. The knowledge of the good health of the garden 
relieves and frees and comforts the eater. The same goes for eating meat. 
The thought of the good pasture and of the calf contentedly grazing flavors 
the steak. Some, I know, will think it blood-thirsty or worse to eat a fellow 
creature you have known all its life. On the contrary, I think it means that 
you eat with understanding and with gratitude. A significant part of the 
pleasure of eating is one's accurate consciousness of the lives and the world 
from which food comes. The pleasure of eating, then, may be the best avail- 
able standard of our health. And this pleasure, I think, is pretty fully avail- 
able to the urban consumer who will make the necessary effort. 

I mentioned earlier the politics, esthetics, and ethics of food. But to 
speak of the pleasure of eating is to go beyond those categories. Eating with 
the fullest pleasure— pleasure, that is, that does not depend on ignorance-is 
perhaps the profoundest enactment of our connection with the world. In 
this pleasure we experience and celebrate our dependence and our grati- 
tude, for we are living from mystery, from creatures we did not make and 
powers we cannot comprehend.When I think of the meaning of food, I 
always remember these lines by the poet William Carlos Williams, which 
seem to me merely honest: 

There is nothing to eat, 
seek it where you will, 
but of the body of the Lord. 
The blessed plants 
and the sea, yield it 
to the imagination 
intact. 



About the Author 



Author of fifty books of fiction, poetry, and essays, Wendell Berry has 
farmed a hillside in his native Henry County, Kentucky, with his wife 
Tanya for over forty years. He has received numerous awards for his work, 
including the T.S. Eliot Award, the Aiken Taylor Award for poetry, the 
John Hay Award of the Orion Society, and recently the Cleanth Brooks 
Medal for Excellence in Southern Letters and the Louis Bromfield Society 
Award. 



223